Conflict inside and outside: Social comparisons and attention shifts in multidivisional firms

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2556
Published date01 July 2017
AuthorRichard A. Bettis,Songcui Hu,Zi‐Lin He,Daniela P. Blettner
Date01 July 2017
Strategic Management Journal
Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 1435–1454 (2017)
Published online EarlyView 1 November2016 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2556
Received 2 October 2014;Final revision received11 April 2016
CONFLICT INSIDE AND OUTSIDE: SOCIAL
COMPARISONS AND ATTENTION SHIFTS IN
MULTIDIVISIONAL FIRMS
SONGCUI HU,1*ZI-LIN HE,2DANIELA P. BLETTNER,3and RICHARD A.
BETTIS4
1Eller College of Management, Department of Management and Organizations,
University of Arizona, Tucson, Arizona, U.S.A.
2School of Economics and Management, Department of Management, Tilburg
University, Tilburg, Netherlands
3Beedie School of Business, Strategy / Technology and Operations Management
Department, Simon Fraser University, Burnaby, British Columbia, Canada
4Kenan-Flagler Business School, Strategy and Entrepreneurship Department,
University of North Carolina-Chapel Hill, Chapel Hill, North Carolina, U.S.A.
Research summary: Behavioral Theory highlights the crucial role of social comparisons in
attention allocation in adaptive aspirations. Yet, both the specication of social reference points
and the dynamics of attention allocation have received little scholarly examination. We address
performance feedback from two social reference points relative to divisions in multidivisional
rms: economic reference point and political reference point. Comparing divisional performance
with the two reference points can give consistent or inconsistent feedback, which has important
consequences for the dynamics of attention allocation in adaptive aspirations. We nd consistent
feedback leads to more attention to own experience, while inconsistent feedback results in more
attention to the social referencepoint the focal division underperforms. Results reveal that political
reference point plays an important rolein determining managerial attention allocation.
Managerial summary: This article is based on how goal-based performance of divisions relative
to both their relevant external marketrivals and sister divisions in multidivisional rms inuences
corporate resource allocation. As a result, various combinations of performance against the two
groups of peers drive the reallocation of divisional management attention. We show that specic
attention shifts occur on average as a function of the focal division’s performance relative to the
marketplace performance and that of sister divisions. Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
INTRODUCTION
A central tenet of the Behavioral Theory of
the Firm (BTOF) is that performance feedback
Keywords: adaptive aspirations; social comparison; polit-
ical coalition; attention allocation; multidivisional rms
*Correspondence to: Songcui Hu, Eller College of Manage-
ment, University of Arizona, 1130 E. Helen St., McClel-
land Hall RM 405MM Tucson, Arizona 85721. E-mail:
songcuih@email.arizona.edu
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
directs how organizations learn and adapt (Cyert
and March, 1963). The generalized model of
performance feedback depends on a satisfactory
performance level— referred to as the aspiration
level— against which an organization compares its
actual performance. According to BTOF (Cyert
and March, 1963), organizations adapt their aspi-
rations based on historical comparisons with their
own experience (i.e., prior aspiration and prior
performance) and social comparisons with others’
experience (i.e., others’ performance). That is,
1436 S. Hu et al.
organizations allocate attention to these different
reference points when adapting their aspirations.
While own experience is generally well dened,
there is considerable ambiguity in the specication
of social reference groups, a crucial but largely
neglected source of rm heterogeneity (e.g.,
Massini, Lewin, and Greve, 2005; Washburn and
Bromiley, 2012).
We focus on social comparisons and the related
feedback from social reference points in adaptive
aspirations. Notwithstanding the well recognized
importance of social comparisons in adaptive aspi-
rations, the selection of social reference groups
remains underexplored and lacks theoretical devel-
opment. Extant empirical studies (e.g., Audia and
Greve, 2006; Baum and Dahlin, 2007; Greve, 1998;
Miller and Chen, 2004) have largely assumed an
entire population of external marketplace competi-
tors as the reference group, which we call the eco-
nomic reference group, and the mean or median
performance of this reference group as the social
reference point, which we call the economic refer-
ence point. This simplied specication of a sin-
gle reference group has provided important insights.
However, recent studies (e.g., Massini etal., 2005;
Moliterno, Beck, and Beckman, 2014; Washburn
and Bromiley,2012) have questioned this and called
for a more careful specication of social refer-
ence groups to increase the precision and realism
of performance feedback models. Furthermore, the
rm-level aspiration has been the focus of these
studies whereas rms can have different aspirations
across different levels of an organizational hierar-
chy (March and Simon, 1958), with varying impli-
cations for adaptation of business units or divisions
within the rm (Gaba and Joseph, 2013; Vissa,
Greve, and Chen, 2010).
We extend the study of attention allocation in
adaptive aspirations to divisions of multidivisional
rms by introducing a second social reference
group, consisting of sister divisions that compete
for corporate resources, in addition to the economic
reference group1. With varying degrees of cen-
tralization (or alternatively divisional autonomy),
multidivisional rms feature headquarters that allo-
cate resources among divisions and divisions that
focus on business-level strategy, implementation,
1In this study, we do not differentiate between “divisions” and
“business units” or other similar terminology; similarly, we do
not differentiate between “multidivisional rms” and “diversied
rms.”
and operations (Chandler, 1962; Williamson,1975).
While corporate strategy often dictates that divi-
sions or business units are designed to create syn-
ergies from sharing capabilities and resources such
as manufacturing or distribution (Ansoff, 1965;
Collins and Montgomery, 1997), it is well estab-
lished that competition for corporate resources
among divisions of multidivisional rms exists.
Depending on the particular rm and the degree of
centralization, this internal competition may vary
in intensity. Following March (1962), and Cyert
and March (1963), we model the overall rm as a
conict management system or political coalition
of members with different preference functions2.
Cyert and March (1963) explicitly state that com-
plete goal consistency among the different coalition
members is generally not achievable: “Except at the
level of nonoperational objectives, there is no inter-
nal consensus. The procedures for ‘resolving’ such
conict do not reduce all goals to a common dimen-
sion or even make them obviously internally consis-
tent” (Cyert and March, 1963: 117).
We submit that the management teams of differ-
ent divisions within a multidivisional rm represent
different coalition members with divergent prefer-
ence functions. They often manipulate information,
misdiagnose problems, and devise solutions in
ways that reinforce their power and importance
relative to other members of the coalition (March,
1988; Pfeffer, 1992). They also resort to vari-
ous “inuence activities” to win more favorable
treatment from the corporate ofce, for instance,
in budget allocation, human resources, and new
product introduction (Lechner and Floyd, 2012;
Milgrom and Roberts, 1988). Getting a larger share
of corporate resources means increased prestige for
division managers and more resources to invest in
division projects. This results in a second social
reference group for each division,the political
reference group consisting of sister divisions, and
the associated political reference point representing
the performance of sister divisions.
It is important to incorporate both economic
and political reference points into division-level
adaptive aspirations of multidivisional rms, since
2For those unfamiliar with the concept of a political coalition,
a reasonable example is the Democratic Party in the USA.
As a political coalition, this party consists largely of union
members, the poor, teachers, single women, governmentworkers,
minorities, college professors, and young voters. These groups
have different goals and interests on some important issues, but
cooperate in a manner that benets all to some degree.
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 1435–1454 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT