Confidence Management: On Interpersonal Comparisons in Teams

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12037
AuthorBauke Visser,Benoît S. Y. Crutzen,Otto H. Swank
Published date01 December 2013
Date01 December 2013
Confidence Management: On Interpersonal
Comparisons in Teams
BENOˆ
IT S. Y. CRUTZEN
Department of Economics, Erasmus School of Economics,
Erasmus University Rotterdam, DR Rotterdam
The Netherlands
crutzen@ese.eur.nl
OTTO H. SWANK
Department of Economics, Erasmus School of Economics
Erasmus University Rotterdam, DR Rotterdam,
The Netherlands; and Tinbergen Institute, Amsterdam, The Netherlands
swank@ese.eur.nl
BAUKE VISSER
Department of Economics, Erasmus School of Economics
Erasmus University Rotterdam, DR Rotterdam,
The Netherlands; and Tinbergen Institute, Amsterdam, The Netherlands
bvisser@ese.eur.nl
Organizations differ in the degree to which they differentiate employees by ability. We analyze
how the effect of differentiation on employee morale may explain this variation. We characterize
sufficient conditions for the manager to refrain from differentiation. She refrains from differ-
entiation when employees are of similar ability, especially if absolute levels are high. Avoiding
differentiation boosts the self-image of employees. To limit the negative effects of differentiation,
the manager’s strategy often relies on the coarsest message set possible. The likelihood that the
manager differentiates depends on the presence of synergies between employees and on the con-
vexity of the cost of effort function. Finally, we show that in the absence of commitment no
differentiation is chosen too often.
“There’s differentiation for all of us in our first 20 years. Why should it stop
in the workplace?” (in Welch 2001, former CEO of General Electric).
“Comparisons are odious” (Saying recorded from the mid-fifteenth century)
1. Introduction
An employee who has imperfect knowledge about his ability or his performance may try
to infer information from how he is being treated by his supervisor. A manager should
We thank a co-editor and two referees for their comments. We also gratefully acknowledge feedback from
the audience at presentations at ESEM 2008 meeting in Milan, the Erasmus School of Economics, European
University Institute, University of Essex, the University of Groningen, and HEC Montreal. Special thanks
are due to Leon Bettendorf, Pascal Courty, Robert Dur, Mike Gibbs, Maarten Goos, Marco Haan, Giuseppe
Moscarini, Karl Schlag, and, in particular, Vladimir Karamychev. Part of this paper was written while Bauke
Visser was a Fernand Braudel Fellow at the EUI.
C2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume22, Number 4, Winter 2013, 744–767
Confidence Management 745
take this into account when deciding what information to disclose, either verbally or
through the actions that she takes.
The idea that people increase their self-knowledge by viewing themselves through
the eyes of others is well-known to social psychologists. It is known as the “looking-glass
self.” B´
enabou and Tirole (2003), BT, formalize this concept to show that rewards may
have a hidden cost, because a reward may signal that the manager does not trust the
employee. Giving a challenging task to a subordinate, by contrast, signals confidence
and consequently motivates.1In BT an employee wants to have an accurate perception
of his ability to make a proper decision on how much effort to exert.2With effort and
ability being complements, the more the employee is confident about his ability, the
more effort he exerts.3In such an environment, managers want employees to believe
they are as able as possible.
The aim of this paper is to analyze the looking-glass self in a context in which
agents gain self-knowledge by considering how they are being treated in comparison
with other agents. That is, we study multi-agent settings: the manager is responsible for
the performance of a unit in which various employees work. Total output depends on
individual contributions and possibly on a synergetic, team component.
Comparisons among employees also play a key role in the recent literature on in-
terim performance feedback in tournaments. The main consideration is whether making
differences among contestants public increases or decreases total performance of these
contestants. The existing literature has uncovered a number of important effects that the
provision of interim feedback can have on effort exerted before and after feedback is
given. The exact effects depend on whether individual output is determined exclusively
by effort or also by an employee’s ability, and on the interaction between effort and
ability, see Lizzeri et al. (1993), Ertac (2005), Gershkov and Perry (2009), Aoyagi (2010),
Ederer (2010), Casas-Arce and As´
ıs Mart´
ınez-Jerez (2009), and Goltsman and Mukherjee
(2010).
Apart from the fact that the employees in our model are not contestants, our pa-
per differs from the above papers and the literature on feedback in tournaments more
generally as it relaxes two assumptions that are commonly made in that literature.
First, that literature typically assumes that the manager commits to a disclosure policy
before she observes actual interim information.4The main reason is that this “allows
[one] to suppress considerations of incentive problems on behalf of the principal such
as misreporting the first-period output difference to elicit higher efforts or to selec-
tively announce interim information” (Ederer 2010, p. 7405). Second, the manager is
constrained to choose between truthfully revealing any and all differences in realized
interim outcomes and providing no information at all. As a result of these assumptions,
considerations on what can be credibly conveyed through feedback, and the precision of
that information are suppressed. In our paper, both the issue of incentive compatibility
and of the informational content of feedback are key.
1. See also Ishida (2006) and Swank and Visser (2007).
2. In BT, a person wants to learn about himself to maker better decisions. Psychologists have paid much
attention to a person’s desire to obtain accurate self-knowledge from evaluations. One source of information
are other persons’ appraisals (Felson, 1993; Baumeister,1998). A problem is that accurate feedback on abilities
is rare (Jones and Wortman,1973). Feedback tends to be too positive (Brown and Dutton, 1995).
3. BT also pay some attention to the case in which effort and ability are substitutes.
4. G¨
urtler and Harbring (2010) is an exception. We discuss their paper shortly.
5. Ederer does discuss the implications of relaxing the commitment assumption but only in the context
where effort and ability enter additively in the production of output. In this paper, effort and ability are
complements which raises interesting commitment issues.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT