Competing for Consumers with Self‐Control Problems

Published date01 March 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12147
Date01 March 2016
AuthorAlexei Alexandrov
Competing for Consumers with Self-Control
Problems
ALEXEI ALEXANDROV
Office of Research
U.S. Consumer Financial Protection Bureau
Washington, D.C.
Alexei.Alexandrov@cfpb.gov
I examine strategic implications of competing for consumers with self-control problems. For in-
vestment goods, like health clubs, I find that the equilibrium sign-up (lump-sum) fees decrease
when competition intensifies, similarly to prices in standard oligopoly models. However,the equi-
librium attendance (per-unit) price increases due to firms’ deteriorated ability to take advantage of
consumers’ self-control problems. Moreover, firms earn less profit due to consumers’ self-control
problems—the firms have a unilateral incentive to charge per-unit fees lower than the marginal
cost; however, they cannot make up the lost margins by increasing the lump-sum fee, due to
competition. I also show that for plausible parameter regions the market adjusts to consumers’
self-control problem in such a way that firms play the standard equilibrium strategies that they
would have engaged in with fully rational consumers, with identical market outcomes. Most of
the results are qualitatively the same for leisure goods (for example, credit cards); however, some
results are reversed: the per-unit fees are higher than marginal cost and decrease as competition
intensifies.
1. Introduction
How does consumer irrationality affect the market equilibrium? If consumers were
to behave irrationally, would this affect outcomes in a particular way that could be
distinguished from market equilibria when consumers behave rationally? My analysis
suggests that market institutions would adjust to irrational behavior, which can alter the
effects of consumer irrationality on market outcomes. In this paper, I examine the effects
of one form of consumer irrationality—self-control problems—and develop a model for
firm strategy. I derive the optimal strategies for the initial lump-sum payment and the
usage (attendance) price in a market with several strategic firms, which are aware of
consumers’ problems with self-control (time-inconsistency).
I consider the implications of consumer self-control problems with respect to in-
vestment goods and leisure goods. Investment goods have immediate costs associ-
ated with one of the actions that consumers can take, as well as future benefits if the
I thank Priscilla Medeiros for getting me interested in this problem; Simon Loertscher and Michael Raith
for their detailed suggestions; Paul Heidhues, Ted O’Donoghue, Jeremy Tobacman, and participants of the
International Industrial Organization Conference for their comments on a much earlier draft; Thomas Gresik,
Chun-Hui Miao, and Sendhil Mullainathan for their comments on a more current draft; and the co-editor and
two anonymous referees. Some of the work was completed while the author was an assistant professor of
economics and management at the University of Rochester. The views expressed arethose of the author and
do not necessarily represent those of the Director of the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau nor those of
the staff.
Published 2015. This article is a U.S. Government work and is in the public domain in the USA.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume25, Number 1, Spring 2016, 179–194
180 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
consumers pursue this action. One example is health clubs, in which a consumer expe-
riences private disutility and may have to pay a usage price to attend, but attendance
yields some future health benefit. Leisure goods are the opposite of investment goods,
associating a current benefit with one of the actions, and a future cost if that action is
chosen. Some examples of leisure goods are credit cards or unhealthy products, where
current consumption implies a consequence later, in either monetary or health terms.1
Firms selling investment goods or services, health clubs for example, have two
major pricing tools at their disposal: the lump-sum fee which consumers pay when they
sign up and the attendance price which consumers pay each time they attend. With fully
rational consumers, the firms compete on the lump-sum fee, with the attendance price
equal to the marginal cost of the health club. However, if consumers have self-control
problems, DellaVigna and Malmendier (2004) showed that the optimal attendance price
is lower than the health club’s marginal cost both in the monopoly and in the perfect
competition scenario. A low attendance price and a high lump-sum fee allow the firm
to exploit consumers’ self-control problems, thus making the firm more profitable since
some consumers pay the lump-sum fee, but do not attend, so that the firm does not incur
the marginal cost.
Whether consumers indeed have self-control problems or other forms of irra-
tionality in a given market is an empirical question. I simply show the firms’ strategies
assuming that consumers do have self-control problems, and that for some of the param-
eter regions it does not matter for final market outcomes whether consumers actually
have any self-control problems.
I show that when firms compete strategically, the lump-sum fee follows the fa-
miliar (Hotelling) comparative statics: the more competitive (less differentiated) firms
become, the lower the fee is. Moreover, if the market is covered in the spatial differen-
tiation model, the lump-sum fee is exactly what it would have been with fully rational
consumers: the market adjusts in such a way that the outcome and comparative statics
with respect to lump-sum price are indistinguishable from the outcome with fully ra-
tional consumers.2On the other hand, the attendance price has different comparative
statics: lower differentiation does not allow firms to exploit consumers’ biases, pushing
the equilibrium attendance price higher, closer to the firms’ marginal cost.3As a mo-
nopolist, as in DellaVigna and Malmendier (2004), a firm has an incentive to charge an
attendance price lower than its marginal cost, while more than making up for it on the
front end. This incentive continues to exist as firms become more competitive; however,
the firms’ ability to make up for it on the front end diminishes. Thus, we see the resulting
comparative static of firms pricing their products closer to marginal cost as they become
more competitive, but closer to marginal cost happens to mean a higher attendance price
for markets with investment products.
1. The term leisure good is chosen to correspond to the earlier literature. Arguably, a more proper term
is a good with delayed cost, and it should not be confused with the more colloquial definition of leisure
good. Vacations would be colloquially characterized as leisure goods, but arenot leisure goods according to
the definition above (unless one pays for them with their credit card, but on the other hand, for many of us
it could be an investment good from the perspective of not being productive during the vacation, with the
delayed benefit of being much more productive after). Similarly, while cigarettes would not be colloquially
characterized as leisure goods, they would be a leisure good according to the definition above since this
product has a delayed cost.
2. The market is covered when consumers have no outside option. This assumption does not impose any
restrictions on cross-elasticities between the firms.
3. Chen and Riordan (2008) show how competition can increase prices in a fully rational model for a given
set of parameters, when the marginal consumer is less elastic in duopoly.Thomadsen et al. (2014) show that a
low-quality entrant might result in increased prices and profits for the incumbents.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT