Comparing Asset Pricing Models

AuthorJAY SHANKEN,FRANCISCO BARILLAS
Date01 April 2018
Published date01 April 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12607
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIII, NO. 2 APRIL 2018
Comparing Asset Pricing Models
FRANCISCO BARILLAS and JAY SHANKEN
ABSTRACT
A Bayesian asset pricing test is derived that is easily computed in closed form from
the standard F-statistic. Given a set of candidate traded factors, we develop a related
test procedure that permits the computation of model probabilities for the collection
of all possible pricing models that are based on subsets of the given factors. We find
that the recent models of Hou, Xue, and Zhang (2015a, 2015b) and Fama and French
(2015, 2016) are dominated by a variety of models that include a momentum factor,
along with value and profitability factors that are updated monthly.
GIVEN THE VARIETY OF PORTFOLIO-BASED factors that have been examined by re-
searchers, it is important to understand how best to combine them in a parsi-
monious asset pricing model for expected returns, one that excludes redundant
factors. Although there are standard econometric techniques for evaluating the
adequacy of a single model, a satisfactory statistical methodology for identi-
fying the best factor pricing model(s) is conspicuously lacking in investment
research applications. In this paper,we develop an easy-to-implement Bayesian
procedure that allows us to compute model probabilities for the collection of all
possible pricing models that can be formed from a given set of factors.
Beginning with the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) of Sharpe (1964)and
Lintner (1965), the asset pricing literature has attempted to understand the
determination of risk premia on financial securities. The central theme of this
literature is that a security’s risk premium should depend on the security’s
market beta or other measure(s) of systematic risk. In a classic test of the
CAPM that builds on Jensen (1968), Black, Jensen, and Scholes (1972) examine
the intercepts in time-series regressions of excess test portfolio returns on
market excess returns. Given the CAPM implication that the market portfolio
is efficient, these intercepts or “alphas” should be zero. A joint F-test of this
hypothesis is later developed by Gibbons, Ross, and Shanken (1989), henceforth
Barillas and Shanken are from the Goizueta Business School at Emory University.Shanken is
also from the National Bureau of Economic Research. Thanks to two anonymous referees, Rohit
Allena, Doron Avramov, Mark Fisher, Amit Goyal, Lubos Pastor, Seth Pruitt, Tim Simin, Ken
Singleton (the Editor), Rex Thompson, Pietro Veronesi, and seminar participants at the Northern
Finance Association meeting, Southern Methodist University,the Universities of Arizona, Geneva,
Hong Kong, Lausanne, Luxembourg, Michigan, Pennsylvania, and Singapore, Hong Kong Univer-
sity of Science and Technology, Imperial College, National University of Singapore, Ohio State
University,and Florida International University. We have read the Journal of Finance’s disclosure
policy and have no conflicts of interest to disclose.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12607
715
716 The Journal of Finance R
GRS, who also explore the relation between the test statistic and standard
portfolio geometry.1
In recent years, a variety of multifactor asset pricing models have been
explored. Although tests of the individual models are routinely reported, these
tests often suggest “rejection” of the implied restrictions, especially when the
data sets are large (e.g., Fama and French (2016)). However, a relatively large
p-value may say more about imprecision in estimating a particular model’s
alphas than the adequacy of that model.2Simple statistical tools with which to
analyze the various models jointly in a model-comparison framework are thus
sorely needed. The information that our methodology provides about relative
model likelihoods complements that obtained from classical asset pricing tests
and is more in the spirit of the adage “it takes a model to beat a model.” 3
Like other asset pricing analyses based on alphas, we require that the bench-
mark factors are traded portfolio excess returns or return spreads. For exam-
ple, in addition to the market excess return, Mkt, the influential three-factor
model of Fama and French (1993), hereafter FF3, includes a book-to-market
or “value” factor, HML (high-low), and a size factor, SMB (small-big), based
on stock market capitalization. Although consumption growth and intertem-
poral hedge factors are not traded, one can always substitute (maximally cor-
related) mimicking portfolios for the nontraded factors.4Although this intro-
duces additional estimation issues, simple spread-portfolio factors are often
viewed as proxies for the relevant mimicking portfolios (e.g., Fama and French
(1996)).
We begin by analyzing the joint alpha restriction for a set of test assets in
a Bayesian setting.5Prior beliefs about the extent of model mispricing are
economically motivated and accommodate traditional risk-based views as well
as more behavioral perspectives. The posterior probability that the zero-alpha
restriction holds is then shown to be an easy-to-calculate function of the GRS F-
statistic. Our related model-comparison methodology is likewise computation-
ally straightforward. This procedure builds on results in Barillas and Shanken
(2017), who highlight the fact that, for several widely accepted criteria, model
comparison with traded factors only requires examination of each model’s abil-
ity to price the factors in the other models.
1See related work by Treynor and Black (1973) and Jobson and Korkie (1982).
2De Moor, Dhaene, and Sercu (2015) suggest a calculation that highlights the extent to which
differences in p-values may be influenced by differences in estimation precision across models, but
they do not provide a formal hypothesis test.
3Avramovand Chao (2006) also explore Bayesian model comparison for asset pricing models. As
we explain in the next two sections, their methodology is quite different from that developed here.
A recent paper by Kan, Robotti, and Shanken (2013) provides asymptotic results for comparing
model R2s in a cross-sectional regression framework. Chen, Roll, and Ross (1986) nest the CAPM
in a multifactor model with betas on macro-related factors included in cross-sectional regressions.
In other Bayesian applications, Malatesta and Thompson (1993) apply methods for comparing
multiple hypotheses in a corporate finance event-study context.
4See Merton (1973) and Breeden (1979), especially footnote 8.
5See earlier work by Shanken (1987b), Harvey and Zhou (1990), and McCulloch and Rossi
(1991).
Comparing Asset Pricing Models 717
The observation that all models are necessarily simplifications of reality and
hence must be false in a literal sense motivates an evaluation of whether a
model holds approximately, rather than as a sharp null hypothesis. Additional
motivation comes from recognizing that the factors used in asset pricing tests
are generally proxies for the relevant theoretical factors.6With these consid-
erations in mind, we extend our results to obtain simple formulas for testing
the more plausible approximate models. As a warm up, we consider all models
that can be obtained using subsets of the FF3 factors Mkt, HML, and SMB.A
nice aspect of the Bayesian approach is that it permits comparison of nested
models like CAPM and FF3, as well as the nonnested models {Mkt HML}and
{Mkt SMB}. Moreover, we are able to simultaneously compare all of the models,
as opposed to standard classical approaches that involve pairwise model com-
parison (e.g., Vuong (1989)). Over the period 1972 to 2015, the alphas for HML
when regressed on Mkt or Mkt and SMB are highly “significant,” whereas the
alphas for SMB when regressed on Mkt or Mkt and HML are modest. Our pro-
cedure aggregates all of this evidence, arriving at posterior probabilities with
our benchmark prior of 60% for the two-factor model {Mkt HML} and 39% for
FF3, with the remaining 1% split between CAPM and {Mkt SMB}.
In our main empirical application, we compare models that combine many
prominent factors from the literature. In addition to the FF3 factors, we con-
sider the momentum factor, UMD (up minus down), introduced by Carhart
(1997) and motivated by Jegadeesh and Titman (1993). We also include fac-
tors from the recently proposed five-factor model of Fama and French (2015),
hereafter FF5.7These are RMW (robust minus weak), which is based on
the profitability of firms, and CMA (conservative minus aggressive), which
is related to firms’ net investments. Hou, Xue, and Zhang (2015a,2015b),
henceforth HXZ, propose their own versions of the size (ME), investment
(IA), and profitability (ROE) factors, which we also examine. In particu-
lar, ROE incorporates the most recent earnings information from quarterly
data. Finally, we consider the value factor HMLmfrom Asness and Frazzini
(2013), which is based on book-to-market rankings that use the most recent
monthly stock price in the denominator. In total, we have 10 factors in our
analysis.
Rather than mechanically apply our methodology with all nine of the non-
market factors treated symmetrically, we structure the prior so as to recognize
that several of the factors are different versions of the same underlying con-
struct. Therefore, to avoid overfitting, we only consider models that contain
at most one of the factors in each of the following categories: size (SMB or
ME), profitability (RMW or ROE), value (HML or HMLm), and investment
(CMA or IA). The extension of our procedure to accommodate such “categorical
6Kandel and Stambaugh (1987) and Shanken (1987a) analyze pricing restrictions based on
proxies for the market portfolio or other equilibrium benchmark.
7We use the SMB factor from the FF5 model in this paper. Our findings are not sensitive to
whetherweusetheoriginalSMB factor, as the correlation between the two size measures is over
0.99.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT