Company Stock in Defined Contribution Plans: Evidence from Proxy Voting

Date01 March 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/fima.12147
Published date01 March 2017
AuthorHeejin Park
Company Stock in Defined Contribution
Plans: Evidence from Proxy Voting
Heejin Park
I examine whether firms’ decisions to offer company stock in defined contribution (DC) plans
are explained by managers’ corporate control motives. Using a large sample of proxy voting
outcomes, I find that employee ownership in DC plans is significantly and positively associated
with the level of voting support for management-sponsoredproposals. This suggests that managers
encourage employee DC holdings in company stock in order to receive higher voting support in
favor of management. The effects of employee ownership on voting outcomes are significantly
greater in specific subsamples where employee vote is moreimportant to management.
From the perspectiveof employees, holding a large share of their defined contribution (DC) plan
invested in the stock of their employer is inefficient because it exposes them to an unnecessary
amount of diversifiable risk. Further, company stock in DC plans ties the value of the employee’s
human capital to the value of his/her retirement savings. This can lead to a situation where the
employee’s labor income and retirement savings fall simultaneously, exacerbating the personal
effects of negative economic shocks.
However, a nontrivial number of firms offer participants company stock as an investment option
in their DC plans. Moreover, they often offer employer matching with company stock even if
participants choose investment options other than the company’s stock. Holden and VanDerhei
(2003) show that among plans that offer employer stock in DC plans, on average, 38% of DC
assets are in their own company stock as of year-end 2002. Using 11-K filings during the period
from 1991 to 2000, Brown, Liang, and Weisbenner (2006) show that 39.3% of their sample firms
offering company stock in DC plans match with employer stock for employer contributions.
Given that employers’ decisions to include company stock in DC plans lead to unnecessary
risk for their employees, it is natural to question the rationale behind this decision. To date, only a
few studies have attempted to investigate the motivations behind this practice. Forexample, Rauh
(2006) argues that managers offer employees company stock in DC plans as a takeover defense
by showing that the changes in Delaware case law in the mid-1990s—which made takeovers
more difficult for outside shareholders to successfully complete—lowered employee ownership.
Rauh’s (2006) study suggests that employer stock is a substitute takeover defense. Brown et al.
(2006) investigate why companies decide to offer matches in company stock and find that fir ms
that have lower stock price volatility, lower bankruptcy risk, and a defined benefit (DB) plan are
more likely to provide company stock matches.
Motivated byRauh (2006), this paper explores whether f irms’ decisions to offer companystock
in their employees’ DC plans can be explained by managers’ corporate control motives. Since
the market for takeover activityhas not been ver y active since the 1990s, and instead shareholder
Special thanks go to my adviser,Diane Del Guercio, for reading countless drafts and providing invaluable support and
advice. I also thank an anonymous referee, Andrea Anthony, Julian Atanassov, Sudipto Dasgupta, Wei Jiang, Xiaoding
Liu, Keun Jae Park, Raghavendra Rau (Editor), Hai Tran, Jason Turkiela, and Wesley Wilson forhelpful comments and
suggestions.
Heejin Parkis with the Korea Workers’Compensation & Welfare Service in Seoul, South Korea.
Financial Management Spring 2017 pages 155 – 202
156 Financial Management rSpring 2017
activism through the proxy process has been more pervasive, I conduct tests in the setting of
annual proxy voting. In particular, I hypothesize that managers provide company stock in order
to receive a higher level of support for management in proxy voting. This hypothesis assumes
that employee ownersvote in favor of management. This assumption is supported by the fact that
voting rights on employee ownership in DC plans are largely delegated to plan trustees. Further,
plan trustees have voting authority for all unallocated shares as well as those allocated shares
when plan participants do not provide anydirection on voting. Because plan trustees are appointed
by management, the trustees are more likely to support management rather than act in the best
interests of their participants (Chaplinsky and Niehaus, 1990; Gordon and Pound, 1990; Chang
and Mayers, 1992). Even if employee owners participate in voting, because they earn wages that
are fixed claims on the firm’s cash flow (Jensen and Meckling, 1979; Faleye, Mehrotra, and
Morck, 2006), they may vote in favor of management and not in favor of shareholders. This is
because from the employee’s perspective, the present value of expected wages and benefits is
greater than the present value of an employee’s equity stake.
Using a panel of 10,093 US firms with 72,560 management-sponsored proposals and
4,436 shareholder-sponsored proposals over the 2003–2012 period, I find a positive associa-
tion between employeeownership in DC plans and voting support for management.1Specif ically,
firms with higher employee ownership receive higher levels of voting support for management-
sponsored proposals compared to firms with lower employee ownership. In management-
sponsored proposals, the ordinary least squares (OLS) results show that a 1-standard deviation
increase in percent of employee ownership in a firm’s equity market value raises “for” votes by
0.1 percentage points. Even though a small increase in votes for management may have little
impact on whether the proposal passes or fails, this is meaningful given the evidence that a
lower level of votes leads to changes in board, management, and other governance-related is-
sues (Cai, Garner, and Walkling, 2009; Fischer et al., 2009; Yermack, 2010; Ertimur, Ferri, and
Oesch, 2013). The results are robust after controlling for other factors affecting voting outcomes,
such as firms’ f inancial strength, managerial ownership,Institutional Shareholder Ser vices (ISS)
recommendation, voting mechanism, and proxy variables for corporate governance.
I conduct several additional subsample tests. First, I separately examine cases consisting of
management-sponsored proposals opposed by ISS. The previous literature shows that ISS is
the most influential proxy adviser, and votes can be swayed up to 20% due to the influence
of ISS recommendations (Bethel and Gillan, 2002; Cai et al., 2009; Choi, Fisch, and Kahan,
2010). Hence, this is likely to be a situation when the support of a block percentage of employee
ownership can be most useful to management. Simply put, employee voting rights can be more
usefully called for when the level of voting support for management is expected to be lower
due to the influence of a proxy adviser. The nextsubsample test consists of only close votes where
the levels of voting support are either just aboveor below 50%. The rationale for examining close
votes is that if management has information about the likely outcome of voting at a time when
it can do something to change the outcome, managers would encourage trustees and employees
to support their proposals for a successful vote.2Thus, given that the marginal effects of voting
support for management are greater for proposals that have around 50% of voting support, I
1In most cases, management tends to vote for management-sponsored proposals but vote against shareholder-sponsored
proposals. In my sample, more than 99.9% of management proposals are recommended by management, while 0.03%
of shareholder proposals are recommended by management. Therefore, voting support in favor of management can be
interpreted as having higher levels of voting support for management-sponsored proposal but lower levels of voting
support for shareholder-sponsored proposals.
2Listokin (2008) finds that there is a large difference between the frequency of management-sponsored proposals passing
with votes just above 50% and the frequency of proposals failing with votes just below 50%.In this study, close votes
Park rCompany Stock in Defined Contribution Plans 157
expect that the results will be stronger in close votes.3Last, I conduct subsample tests separately
for director election and say on pay frequency proposals. Specifically, compensation-related
proposals are closely related to managerial entrenchment because they directly influence the
economic welfare of management. The results show that the effect of employee ownership in
voting outcomes is significantly greater for director election with more than 20% withheld and
for say on pay frequency proposals.
Overall, I find that the effects of employee ownership are much larger for proposals in these
subsamples. For example, in say on pay frequency proposals, an increase in the percent of
employee ownership in firms’ equity market value by 1 standard deviation is associated with an
increase in the proportion of “for” votes of 0.97 percentage points. Further, once it is combined
with managerial ownership, the effect is even stronger. Specifically, increases in the percent of
employee ownership by 1 standard deviation and percent of managerial ownership by 1 standard
deviation raise the proportion of “for” votes by 3.86 percentage points. Considering that Cai
et al. (2009) find that a 1% decrease in the average votes for compensation committee members
associates with reductions in abnormal chief executive officer (CEO) compensation by $143,000
in the following year, the effects of employee ownership are economically meaningful.
My paper relates to several strands of literature. First, I complement Rauh’s (2006) f indings
by providing evidence that corporate control motives are still important in an era when hostile
takeovers are not significant. In particular, the findings of this paper indicate that managers offer
company stock in DC plans to their employees in order to receive higher voting support for
management in spite of unnecessary risk to their employees. As such, my findings contribute to
understanding the purpose of employee ownership in pension plans from the view of employers
(Mitchell and Utkus, 2002; Brown et al., 2006).
Second, my findings contribute to a growing literature on shareholder voting. A large body of
research has focused on the influence of proxy advisers’ recommendations on voting outcomes
(Bethel and Gillan, 2002; Cai et al., 2009; Alexander et al., 2010; Choi et al., 2010) or voting
behavior of institutional investors(Gillan and Starks, 2000; Parrino, Sias, and Starks, 2003; Davis
and Kim, 2007; Cotter, Palmiter, and Thomas, 2011; Morgan et al., 2011; Ashraf, Jayaraman,
and Ryan, 2012). In particular, this paper sheds light on a limited body of literature concerning
methods management may use to try to have influence on voting outcomes (Ferri and Oesch,
2014).
Finally, my paper also contributes to a growing area of research focused on DC plans. As the size
and importance of DC plans increase, it is evident that employees must become more responsible
for their ownretirement income security. However,an extensiveliterature on behavioral economics
suggests that plan participants struggle to make optimal investment decisions due to choice and
information overload (Benartzi and Thaler, 2001; Iyengar, Huberman, and Jiang, 2004; Iyengar
and Kamenica, 2006), undefined preferences and investment menu design (Benartzi and Thaler,
2001, 2002; Mitchell and Utkus, 2002; Elton, Gruber, and Blake, 2006), and procrastination and
inertia (Benartzi and Thaler, 2002; Choi, Madrian, and Metrick, 2002). Managers’ decisions to
offer employees company stock in DC plans in order to increase managerial power may lead
are defined as the levels of voting support between 30% and 70%. As shown in Figure A1 in the Appendix, there is a
discontinuity in the distribution of voting outcomes in management-sponsored votes at the 50% level.
3This is because with a small shift, management can win the proposal as the marginal effect in close votes of voting
shift from employees and trustees is large. However, management will withdraw or alter the proposal if managers predict
that the proposal will fail with far below 50% support. Furthermore, management will not act if managers predict that
the proposal will win with far above 50% support. Due to a limited sample size, here, close votes are defined somewhat
broadly as situations where the levels of voting support are between 30% and 70% and the proposals need greater than
50% support to pass.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT