Common ownership, institutional investors, and welfare

AuthorRune Stenbacka,Oz Shy
Published date01 July 2020
Date01 July 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12380
J Econ Manage Strat. 2020;29:706723.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems706
|
© 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
Received: 15 April 2019
|
Revised: 3 December 2019
|
Accepted: 4 May 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12380
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Common ownership, institutional investors, and welfare
Oz Shy
1
|Rune Stenbacka
2
1
Research Department, Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta, Atlanta, Georgia
2
Department of Finance and Economics,
Hanken School of Economics, Helsinki,
Finland
Correspondence
Rune Stenbacka, Department of Finance
and Economics, Hanken School of
Economics, P.O. Box 479, 00101 Helsinki,
Finland.
Email: Rune.Stenbacka@hanken.fi
Abstract
This study evaluates the effects of institutional investors' common ownership
of firms competing in the same market. Overall, common ownership has two
opposing effects: (a) it serves as a device for weakening market competition,
and (b) it induces diversification, thereby reducing portfolio risk. We conduct a
detailed welfare analysis within which the competitionsoftening effects of an
increased degree of common ownership is weighted against the associated
diversification benefits.
1|INTRODUCTION
Recent studies have attracted attention to the increasingly important phenomenon of common ownership of publicly
traded firms (e.g., Azar, Schmalz, & Tecu, 2018; Backus, Conlon, and Sinkinson, 2019b; Gilje, Gormley, and Levit, 2017;
Schmalz, 2018; Seldeslachts, Newham, and BanalEstanol, 2017). In particular, institutional investors often hold
ownership stakes in competing firms belonging to the same industry. He and Huang (2017) present evidence that the
proportion of U.S. public companies with common institutional ownership has increased from below 10% in 1980 to
about 60% in 2014. These public companies include institutional owners that simultaneously hold at least 5% of the
common equity of rival firms in the same industry. Azar (2017) reports a similar trend by reference to a finding that
the share of S&P 500 firms with overlapping owners holding at least 3% ownership stakes in firms belonging to the same
industry has increased from 25% to 90% during the period from 2000 to 2010.
From a theoretical perspective, common ownership can be expected to soften competition because managers, who
maximize the returns to their shareholders, internalize the effects their product market decisions have on rivals. This is the
central mechanism developed in the model of overlapping intraindustry ownership by O'Brien and Salop (2000). Several
empirical studies have recently estimated the effects on competition of common ownership in different industries. Azar et al.
(2018) present evidence to support the conclusion that common ownership raised airfares by relating these prices to
measures of concentration which are adjusted to take common ownership into account. Further, Azar, Raina, and Schmalz
(2016) show similar effects of common ownership on spreads and fees for banking products.
1
Newham, Seldeslachts, and
BanalEstañol (2018) explore the effects of common ownership on entry. They employ data from the pharmaceutical industry
to empirically establish that common ownership with the incumbent brand firm reduces the probability of generic entry.
In this analysis, we focus on a configuration where consumers can allocate their savings into one of two competing
institutional investors. The institutional investors channel their funds to acquire ownership in product market firms
operating in a duopolistic industry. We can think of these institutional investors as pension funds. We initially show
that an increased degree of common ownership relaxes the intensity of product market competition. However, an
increased degree of common ownership also reduces the risks in the intraindustry portfolios of the institutional
owners. Therefore, an increased degree of common ownership defines an interesting tradeoff between relaxed com-
petition in the product market and improved risk diversification in the asset market for riskaverse savers. A detailed
welfare analysis associated with this tradeoff is the main contribution of our study.
Our welfare analysis reveals that the socially optimal degree of common ownership is importantly influenced by two
factors: (a) the degree of risk aversion and (b) the relative weight society assigns to consumption of the final product
versus that assigned to returns on savings via institutional investors. A low relative weight assigned to consumption of
the final product can be interpreted as a society that encourages savings for retirement and discourages excessive
consumption. We characterize in detail how the socially optimal degree of common ownership with risk neutrality
depends on the relative weight placed on consumption of the final good. In particular, we find that under risk neutrality
complete ownership specialization, that is no common ownership at all, is socially optimal as long as the relative weight
on consumption of the final good is sufficiently high. Further, we show analytically that with risk aversion, and for the
class of utility functions with constant relative risk aversion (CRRA), an increase in the degree of risk aversion increases
the socially optimal degree of common ownership. The intuition is that the institutional investors offer more diversified
investment portfolios to their savers if there is a higher degree of common ownership, and the value savers attach to
diversification is increasing as a function of the degree of risk aversion.
Our analysis is linked to a category of theoretical models which have characterized the effects of common own-
ership or overlapping ownership on market performance by applying industrial economics approaches. This category of
models includes O'Brien and Salop (2000), López and Vives (2019), and Shy and Stenbacka (2019), and it is broadly
surveyed in Vives (2019) as well as Section 2of Schmalz (2018). Our present analysis extends this approach to a welfare
analysis within which the competitionsoftening effects of an increased degree of common ownership can be weighted
against the associated diversification benefits.
The recent advances in the analysis of the effects of common ownership have initiated an intense debate among
economists and legal scholars regarding policy implications. Elhauge (2016) and Posner, Morton, and Weyl (2017) have
proposed the introduction of rules to restrict the ability of institutional owners to hold ownership stakes in several firms
operating in the same industry. Other researchers, such as Lambert and Sykuta (2018) and Ginsburg and Klovers
(2018), have forcefully raised arguments against such restrictions. The debate has also entered the policy arena. For
example, in its resolution, dated April 19, 2018, in response to the European Commission's annual report on compe-
tition policy, the European Parliament calls on the Commission to take all necessary measures to deal with the
possible anticompetitive effects of common ownershipand to investigate the effects of common ownership on
European markets, particularly on prices and innovation.
2
Our welfare analysis could be viewed as a central com-
ponent in arguments required to derive effectsbased policy implications because it highlights the tradeoff between
competitionrelaxing effects and diversification benefits associated with an increased degree of common ownership.
It should be pointed out that intraindustry common ownership is by no means the only way in which institutional
investors in general, and pension funds in particular, can diversity their portfolios. Of course, diversification can also be
accomplished by mixing equity from different industries as well as fixed income obligations without owning multiple
competing firms within the same industry. However, as frequently observed, investors can further diversify their
portfolios by acquiring stocks of competing firms within the same industry, and it is the focus of the present study to
analyze this particular aspect. To achieve this goal, we characterize the welfare tradeoff induced by an increased degree
of common ownership as we balance the competitionrelaxing effects against the associated diversification benefits. In
fact, our study matches the priorities suggested in Backus, Conlon, and Sinkinson (2019a) who argue that the most
fruitful direction for future research on the competitive effects of common ownership could involve attempts to
measure those effects within a single industry, with a focus on pairwise profit weights rather than marketlevel
concentration measures as the variable of interest(p. 25).
This study is organized as follows. Section 2designs a static duopoly model to measure how the share value of
institutional investors varies with the degree of their common ownership in firms competing in the same product
market. Section 3solves for the equilibrium profits of the firms and investors as functions of the degree of common
ownership. Section 4analyzes how common ownership affects investors' portfolio risk. Section 5conducts the welfare
analysis of common ownership. Section 6explores several extensions of the model. Section 7presents concluding
comments. Appendices provide algebraic derivations.
2|DUOPOLY COMPETITION, INSTITUTIONAL INVESTORS, AND
COMMON OWNERSHIP
Following Shy and Stenbacka (2019) we introduce institutional investors into a modified duopoly model with two firms
competing based on production decisions in the product market. The two producing firms are owned by two
SHY AND STENBACKA
|
707

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT