Commentary: Reputation and Accountability: Incentives and Reputation as a Harness

AuthorPaul Tucker
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/puar.12686
Published date01 January 2017
Date01 January 2017
Reputation and Accountability: Incentives and Reputation as a Harness 101
Public Administration Review,
Vol. 77, Iss. 1, pp. 101–102. © 2016 by
The American Society for Public Administration.
DOI: 10.1111/puar.12686.
Reputation and Accountability:
Incentives and Reputation as a Harness
Paul Tucker , former deputy governor
of the Bank of England, now chairs the
Systemic Risk Council and is a fellow at the
John F. Kennedy School of Government at
Harvard University. His commentary draws
on his forthcoming book on the legitimacy
of unelected power, to be published by
Princeton University Press.
E-mail: paul_tucker@hks.harvard.edu
Commentary
M artin Lodge and Madalina Busuioc have
written an important article on the need
to consider how the desire for reputation
affects the accountability of public policy agencies. It
could usefully spark additional research and discussion
on the circumstances under which accountability
helps harness agencies to the public good.
It has become commonplace in the literature on
public administration to define accountability very
broadly. Regulators are said to be accountable to those
they regulate, the regulated community s customers,
other interest groups, and the general public. I doubt
whether many practitioners think like that, and when
they do, I suspect they mislead themselves. Regulators
and other administrative agencies are given delegated
mandates by democratically elected legislatures. The
agencies, led by unelected officials, are accountable to
the legislature, which must decide whether to sustain,
reform, or repeal the regime. The views of other
audiences matter to legislative opinion, of course,
but that is not the same as being accountable to
them. Agencies do not stand apart from or above the
democratic state.
Hearings in front of legislative committees are, on
this view, vital to a regime s legitimacy. They perform
many roles, including the “fire alarm” and “police
patrol” functions made famous by political scientists
Mathew McCubbins and Thomas Schwartz. But the
purpose and effect of hearings go further than that
narrow compass of finding error and deterring abuse.
Hearings are, in principle, the central occasion for
spurring and contributing to public debate about the
purposes of a regime and the agency s stewardship of
the regime.
Whether hearings perform that wider role in
practice depends in part on the incentives of the
agency leaders and legislative committee members.
Where, as in the United States, committee members
have near-monopoly rights over tabling legislation,
their reputation turns less on their contribution to
agency oversight. Where, as in the United Kingdom,
committee members have few de jure powers, they
have greater incentives to enhance their prestige (their
reputation among their peers and with the public)
through high-profile oversight of agencies.
In both cases, the reputational incentives are greater
as the profile of an agency becomes higher and its
mission and actions become more salient to the
public. Thus, oversight hearings with central banks
tend to raise committee members’ public profiles
more than hearings with some other kinds of agencies.
My second point concerns “reputation for what?”
If a delegated regime has a vague objective or a
multiplicity of vague objectives, the public debate and
hearings that shape the reputation of an agency and
its overseers form part of a broader process through
which the direction and activities of an agency are
shaped and embedded. This is reputation building
as mission discovery, and it is an underdetermined
process because it is not anchored by a clear goal.
Things are quite different when a mission is clear
and an agency has an objective against which it can
be monitored on the basis of a clear standard (for
central banks, achieving a target for inflation over the
medium term). In those circumstances, an agency s
leaders can be harnessed to the mission if their
reputation, with peers, legislators, and public, can
be made to depend on their success in delivering the
mandated goal.
A prudent—or, if you prefer, a shrewd—agency is a
legitimacy seeker. The desire of its leaders for prestige
and standing can be tethered to a clear goal by its
legislative overseers if their own reputations depend,
in turn, on the quality of their oversight. But absent
a clear objective, accountability can amount to a
process through which an agency and its legislative
overseers either compete for standing or cooperate,
through an elaborate dance, in manufacturing a joint
reputation.
Paul Tucker
Harvard University

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT