Collusion under different pricing schemes

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12392
AuthorFlorian Gössl,Alexander Rasch
Date01 October 2020
Published date01 October 2020
J Econ Manage Strat. 2020;29:910931.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems910
|
© 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
Received: 6 February 2018
|
Revised: 28 February 2020
|
Accepted: 16 June 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12392
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Collusion under different pricing schemes
Florian Gössl
1
|Alexander Rasch
2,3
1
AXA Konzern AG, Cologne, Germany
2
Duesseldorf Institute for Competition
Economics (DICE), Duesseldorf, Germany
3
Leibniz Centre for European Economic
Research (ZEW), Mannheim, Germany
Correspondence
Alexander Rasch, Duesseldorf Institute for
Competition Economics (DICE),
University of Duesseldorf,
Universitaetsstrasse 1, 40225 Duesseldorf,
Germany.
Email: rasch@dice.hhu.de
Abstract
We analyze collusive outcomes under different pricing schemes in a differ-
entiated product market in which customers have elastic demand. Starting
with a situation in which firms can set twopart tariffs to price discriminate, we
consider two policy interventions that ban price discrimination: Firms must set
(a) linear prices or (b) fixed fees. We find that collusion at maximum prices
becomes harder to sustain under linear prices. By contrast, the analysis shows
that the fixed fees policy facilitates collusion at maximum prices. The results
have important implications for competition policy.
1|INTRODUCTION
We analyze the impact of different pricing structures on firms' ability to maintain collusion. We examine the effects of
nonlinear pricing and the outcomes of related regulatory policies designed to address the practice, which is common in
many industries. Examples of businesses that employ nonlinear pricing include amusement parks, gas, media markets,
mobile telecommunications, and electricity. In these industries, the pricing structures typically consist of (at least) two
components: a fixed (entry) fee, which is independent of the quantity demanded, and a linear perunit price.
The question of whether price discrimination helps to fight collusion has received considerable attention from both
an academic and a practical point of view (see some motivating examples below). The literature has analyzed this issue
in terms of cases of firstand thirddegree price discrimination (see below). Generally speaking, these types of price
discrimination are found to be good for competition and make collusion more difficult to sustain. However, the
question of the impact of seconddegree price discrimination on firms' ability to sustain collusion remains unanswered.
This article addresses this gap.
1
We investigate whether and how the possibility of coordinating on multiple price components instead of agreeing
upon one single (linear or fixed) collusive price influences firms' ability to sustain collusion. To derive policy re-
commendations, we also examine the effects on total welfare and customer surplus. To this end, building on the setup
by Yin (2004) who models twopart tariff competition in duopoly, we analyze the incentives to collude under different
pricing schemes in a differentiated products setup (à la Hotelling, 1929) with variable demand. Total demand is elastic,
as local demandthe demand of a single customerdecreases in the price and in the distance to the respective firm
(i.e., considering transport costs). We start by analyzing collusive incentives in the case in which firms can price
discriminate and coordinate on twopart tariffs. Turning to the situations in which price discrimination is prohibited,
we find that the comparison with regard to the sustainability of collusion at monopoly prices crucially depends on the
type of policy interventionthat is, whether authorities order the use of linear or fixed fees only. The scope for
collusion is largest when firms use fixed fees only, whereas collusion is most difficult to sustain when firms set linear
prices only.
What renders collusion particularly less attractive under linear pricing compared with nonlinear pricing is the
higher additional benefit from reducing the linear price: Not only does the reduction enlarge a deviating firm's market
share, but it increases inframarginal demand at the same time. Due to a lower linear collusive price, this effect is less
pronounced under twopart tariffs. Moreover, this effect is even less pronounced under fixed fees, which explains why
collusion at monopoly prices is easiest to sustain in that scenario.
Our analysis has important implications for customer and total welfareand, hence, for competition policy. In any
case, banning price discrimination turns out to be the right thing to do. Our model predicts that when authorities follow
a consumer standard, banning fixed fees is optimal. In this case, consumer surplus is always higher under linear pricing
than under twopart tariffsindependent of whether firms collude or compete. By contrast, when authorities are
interested in maximizing social welfare, our analysis shows that linear prices should be banned. Again, independent of
whether the market is collusive or competitive, welfare is always highest under fixed fees.
1.1 |Motivating cases
Competition authorities have been debating whether to ban price discrimination and what the effects of such a ban on
collusion are. When firms use twopart tariffs as a type of seconddegree price discrimination,
2
a ban can come in two
different forms: banning linear prices or banning fixed prices. Indeed, such regulatory interventions have been pro-
posed in markets in which price discrimination and collusion are important aspects. For example, in the United
Kingdom, the big sixenergy suppliers faced investigations over pricefixing allegations.
3
At the same time, the Office
of Gas and Electricity Markets (Ofgem) introduced several restrictions on the retail residential energy market.
4
A
central proposal by Ofgem was that Ofgem itself would set a standardized (uniform) fixed (or standing) charge for all
standard tariffs, and that suppliers would then compete on a single unit rate for each standard tariff (Littlechild, 2014).
Such an intervention thus equates to banning of fixed fees.
Another prominent example is the market for (mobile) telecommunication services. Numerous investigations across
the world have documented price fixing in this market. Examples include the case of mobile phone service providers in
Hong Kong in 2000 (Chen & Lin, 2002) and a convicted mobile phone cartel in France (de Mesnard, 2009).
5
Moreover,
the different pricing components and subscription plans, which are important in this market, appear to play crucial
roles in these collusive cases. As Larsen (2010) points out in his extensive study of (allegedly) collusive behavior
regarding text messaging in the United States, firms set supracompetitive payperuse (PPU) prices for those customers
who did not opt for a monthly text plan, or exceed their monthly limit of text messages. Indeed, the author suggests that
[a]s a first step, the FCC [Federal Communications Commission] should set a price cap on PPU rates closer to the
marginal cost of the service(p. 242). In other words, competition in the linear price component would be restricted.
6
Furthermore, in an investigation in South Korea, the country's three largest wireless carriers were accused of
collusion and other unfair practices. In June 2017, the government announced measures to lower mobile expenses by
increasing the monthly discount rate for new mobile phone subscribers from 20% to 25%. Additionally, the government
ordered carriers to exempt the basic monthly subscription fee (11,000 won, approximately $9.90 USD) for elderly and
lowincome household members.
7
Similar to the Ofgem example, such an intervention means that firms can no longer
compete in fixed fees.
1.2 |Related literature
Although price discrimination and nonlinear tariffs are important features of antitrust concerns, the literature on the
impact of different pricing schemes on collusion is sparse.
8
Concerning the relationship between thirddegree price
discrimination and collusion, Liu and Serfes (2007) investigate the impact of the availability of customerspecific
information for market segmentation in a linearcity model on the sustainability to collude. A higher degree of market
segmentation accompanied by a more diversified pricing structure is possible as the quality of customer information
increases. The authors show that collusion is harder to sustain as the firms' ability to segment customers improves.
A related study to Liu and Serfes (2007) is Colombo (2010). The author allows for different degrees of product
differentiation (i.e., firms are not located at the extremes of the linear city), and analyzes perfect (or firstdegree) price
discrimination. With perfect price discrimination, firms may set prices based on the exact location of a customer in so
called delivered pricing.
9
The author finds that collusion is easier to sustain the lower transport costs are,
10
and that
colluding on discriminatory prices is harder than on a uniform price.
11
For thirddegree price discrimination, Helfrich and Herweg (2016) find that price discrimination helps to fight
collusion not only under bestresponse asymmetries (lower static Nash equilibrium profits under price discrimination)
GÖSSL AND Rasch
|
911

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT