Chapter V. Monopolization In Telecom And Media Markets

Pages245-298
245
CHAPTER V
MONOPOLIZATION IN TELECOM AND MEDIA
MARKETS
A. The History of Telecommunications Regulation
1. The Age of Regulated Monopoly—1893-1974
Telecommunications has a long history of both regulation and
antitrust litigation. In 1893, after Alexander Graham Bell’s patent on his
“talking machine” expired, a large number of independently owned
telephone companies entered the market for telephone services.1 Often,
independent and AT&T-operated service areas were contained within the
same city requiring consumers to install and pay for service from both
companies if they wanted to place calls routed throughout the city.2
Initially, the independent providers had a strong presence in the market,
and, by 1907, they were on nearly equal footing with AT&T.3 Because
the independent companies were small, separate companies, they were
unable to create an integrated nationwide network.4 Unlike AT&T, they
did not have uniform technical requirements, and thus struggled with
compatibility problems when they tried to integrate their regional
systems.5
Regulation accompanied the growing proliferation of telephone
service and the increasing dominance of AT&T. By 1920, almost every
state had a public utility commission to regulate telephone service.6
Federal regulation also began with the passage of the Mann-Elkins Act in
1910, which subjected telephone companies to the regulation of the
Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC) and required just and reasonable
1. See DECISION TO DIVEST: MAJOR DOCUMENTS IN U.S. V. AT&T, 1974-
1984 Vols. I, II, & III (Christopher H. Sterling, et al. eds., 1986)
[hereinafter DECISION TO DIVEST].
2. Id.
3. Id.
4. Id.
5. Id. at I-4.
6. Id.
246 Telecom Antitrust Handbook
rates.7 But the ICC only had jurisdiction over long-distance telephone
service, leaving a large portion of the industry unregulated.8 Further, the
Mann-Elkins Act did not address the structure of the telephone industry,
and, as a result, consolidation continued.9
By 1913, AT&T had combined its twenty-four local-exchange
affiliates, a long-lines department, Western Electric, and Bell Labs into a
single corporation, leading to concerns about AT&T’s ability to leverage
market power and engage in self-preferential activities.10 AT&T also
obtained patents on nearly all aspects of telephone equipment, and was
the first to enter high-volume and lucrative product markets, then
vertically integrating the manufacture and operation of the telephone.11
AT&T’s competitors, frustrated with the lack of intervention by the ICC,
asked the Department of Justice (DOJ) to investigate.12 On July 24, 1913,
the DOJ filed a federal antitrust suit against AT&T.13
In the fall of 1913, after initial witness testimony and further
investigation by the ICC, Nathan Kingsbury, the president of AT&T, and
then-U.S. Attorney General (later Supreme Court Justice) James
McReynolds, held a series of meetings.14 The resulting agreement
between McReynolds and Kingsbury, memorialized in a series of letters
between the two, came to be known as the Kingsbury Commitment.15
Under the Kingsbury Commitment, AT&T agreed not to acquire
competing telephone companies, to submit pending acquisitions to the
DOJ and ICC for approval, and to interconnect with the independent
local exchanges.16 AT&T also agreed to sell its interest in Western
Union.17 In practice, however, the terms of the Kingsbury Commitment
7. Pub. L. No. 61-218, 36 Stat. 539 (1910).
8. DECISION TO DIVEST, supra note 1, at I-5.
9. Id.
10. See Jim Chen, The Legal Process and Political Economy of
Telecommunications Reform, 97 COLUM. L. REV. 835, 838 (1997).
11. See GERALD BROCK, THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRY: DYNAMICS
OF MARKET STRUCTURE 100 (1981).
12. See PETER TEMIN & LOUIS GALMBOS, THE FALL OF THE BELL SYSTEM 9
(1987).
13. DECISION TO DIVEST, supra note 1, at I-5.
14. Id.
15. Id.
16. Id.
17. TEMIN & GALMBOS, supra note 12, at 10.
Monopolization 247
proved difficult to implement,18 and it was officially dissolved in 1921
by the Willis-Graham Act.19
In 1934, Congress passed the Communications Act (the 1934 Act),
creating the Federal Communications Commission (FCC or
“Commission”), which had the comprehensive power to regulate the
interstate operations of telephone, telegraph, and radio.20 The
Commission was initially created to ensure universal provision of
telephone services at regulated prices.21 At the time, telephony was
considered a natural monopoly, and the economic understanding was that
injecting artificial competition into the industry would create
inefficiencies. The Commission, therefore, was not seen as a means of
promoting competition.22
Nonetheless, the Commission began to investigate AT&T, and in
1938 it produced a report alleging that AT&T engaged in monopolistic
practices.23 With the United States’ entry into World War II, however, no
action was taken on these findings, and AT&T continued to expand its
services to meet the increased demand brought on by war.24
In 1949, the DOJ revisited the FCC investigation and, building on
those findings, conducted its own review.25 The DOJ investigation
culminated in a lawsuit against AT&T in United States District Court for
the District of New Jersey for Sherman Act violations.26 The case settled
in a consent decree in 1956 that kept AT&T’s structure intact but limited
the lines of businesses the company could enter.27
New technologies in the 1950s and 1960s began to challenge
AT&T’s control of communications. Data transmission introduced a new
function for telephone lines, but AT&T, limited by the terms of the 1956
consent decree, could not take advantage of this opportunity.
18. DECISION TO DIVEST, supra note 1, at I-6.
19. Pub. L. No. 67-14, 42 Stat. 27 (1921).
20. DECISION TO DIVEST, supra note 1, at I-7.
21. Aimee M. Adler, Competition in Telephony: Perception or Reality?
Current Barriers to the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 7 J.L. & POLY
571, 574 (1999).
22. Robert Friedrich, Regulatory and Antitrust Implications of Emerging
Competition in the Local Access Telecommunications: How Congress
and the FCC Can Encourage Competition and Technological Progress in
Communications, 80 CORNELL L. REV. 646, 659 (1995).
23. DECISION TO DIVEST, supra note 1, at I-8.
24. Id.
25. Id.
26. Id.
27. Id.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT