Chapter I. Economic Underpinnings: The Economics of Communications Networks, Market Power, and Vertical Foreclosure Theories

Pages1-61
1
CHAPTER I
ECONOMIC UNDERPINNINGS: THE ECONOMICS
OF COMMUNICATIONS NETWORKS, MARKET
POWER, AND VERTICAL FORECLOSURE
THEORIES
A. Introduction
This chapter introduces the concept of market power and explains
the characteristic features of communications markets and providers that
are often relevant to allegations of market power and abuse of market
power in communications industries. The chapter continues with a
discussion of market definition, which is an element in a typical analysis
of whether a firm has market power. It concludes with a general
overview of potential anticompetitive effects that flow from the exercise
of market power, with a particular focus on vertical foreclosure theories.
Vertical foreclosure refers generally to the use of vertical integration or
other vertical restraints by an input supplier to achieve market power in
an output market. In communications networks, theories of vertical
foreclosure have been of particular prominence, and such theories partly
motivated the vertical divestiture from AT&T of the Bell Operating
Companies in the mid-1980s.1 More generally, in communications
networks a supplier of a key input may also be a downstream competitor,
which may have implications for the incentives of the vertically
integrated firm and its customers/competitors.
The application of the vertical foreclosure concept is neither simple
nor straightforward. Vertical integration concerns remain a significant
driver of communications policy and of antitrust litigation initiated by
competitors. As will be discussed in later sections of this chapter,
depending on their alignment with incumbents versus competitors, there
are often fundamental differences among economists in the analysis of
these issues, making a balanced presentation of these issues particularly
challenging.
1. See discussion at part E of this chapter.
2 Telecom Antitrust Handbook
B. An Introduction to Market Power in Communications Markets
With respect to federal oversight of the communications industry, the
concept of market power arises in both the contexts of antitrust
enforcement and economic regulation. The chief goal of the federal
agencies charged with enforcing the U.S. antitrust laws is to prevent the
acquisition of an increased ability to exercise market power and to
prevent the illegal maintenance of market power. For example, mergers
are prohibited under Section 7 of the Clayton Act if their effect “may be
substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly”2 or
are prohibited under Section 1 of the Sherman Act if they constitute a
“contract, combination . . . or conspiracy in restraint of trade.”3 The 2010
Merger Guidelines4 of the federal antitrust agencies lay out the
enforcement policy of these agencies with respect to mergers. The
“unifying theme of these Guidelines is that mergers should not be
permitted to create, enhance, or entrench market power or to facilitate its
exercise.”5 Antitrust enforcement against monopolization or attempted
monopolization is also based on core principles focused on “market
power and separating the legitimate, procompetitive ways it is acquired
and preserved, from the illegitimate, anticompetitive ways.”6
The Federal Communications Commission (FCC) uses a different
framework for evaluating mergers than that of the 2010 Merger
Guidelines—what it terms a broad and flexible” public interest standard.7
However, a key component of the evaluation is a determination of
whether a merger “will allow firms . . . to exercise increased market
power through either unilateral or coordinated anticompetitive
behavior.”8 The FCC also applies the concept of market power in non-
2. 15 U.S.C. § 18.
3. 15 U.S.C. § 1.
4. U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FEDERAL TRADE COMMN, HORIZONTAL
MERGER GUIDELINES (2010), available at www.justice.gov/atr/public/
guidelines/hmg-2010.html [hereinafter 2010 MERGER GUIDELINES].
5. Id. § 1.0.
6. Joel I. Klein, Rethinking Antitrust Policies for the New Economy,
Haas/Berkeley New Economy Forum, May 9, 2000, available at
www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/4707.htm.
7. 47 U.S.C. §§ 214(a), 310(d) (1997); Applications of NYNEX
Corporation Transferor, and Bell Atlantic Corporation Transferee, For
Consent to Transfer Control of NYNEX Corporation and Its Subsidiaries,
12 F.C.C.R. 19985, 19987, ¶ 2 (1997).
8. Application of WorldCom, Inc. and MCI Commc’ns for Transfer of
Control of MCI Commc’ns to WorldCom, Inc., 13 F.C.C.R. 18025,
Economic Underpinnings 3
merger contexts, as when it has chosen to forbear from imposing certain
regulatory requirements (e.g., rate and entry/exit regulation) on non-
dominant carriers (that is, carriers that it has determined to lack market
power).9
Market power is generally defined in economics as the ability to
affect the market price of a good.10 In the economic model of “perfect
competition,” every firm is small relative to the market and products are
homogeneous, so no one firm can affect the market price. In such
markets, long-run equilibrium is achieved when prices are equal to the
marginal cost of the firms in the industry.11 In this case, another way of
expressing this definition of market power is that it involves the ability to
set and sustain prices above marginal cost.12 In general, however, in
multiproduct firms the level of prices even in free-entry, zero-profits
market may exceed marginal cost due to the presence of fixed common
costs,13 and this difference is particularly important for
telecommunications markets where such costs are a significant
proportion of total costs.14 Hence, as a matter of economic theory, market
18036, ¶ 16 (1998) [hereinafter WorldCom/MCI Order]. Nonetheless, the
“public interest” standard affords the FCC considerable leeway in its
merger review, and it has recently adopted the practice of permitting
parties to proposed mergers to take on “voluntary commitments” as a
means of mitigating concerns related to their potential exercise of market
power. See, e.g., SBC Commc’ns and AT&T Corp. Applications for
Approval of Transfer of Control, 20 F.C.C.R. 18290, 18391, ¶ 205
(2005).
9. See, e.g., Report and Order, Competition in the Interstate Interexchange
Marketplace, 6 F.C.C.R. 5880, 5887-89 (1991) (largely eliminating price
regulation upon determination that interexchange carrier AT&T lacked
market power in business services, based on supply and demand elasticity
as well as pricing and market share evidence).
10. ROBERT S. PINDYCK & DANIEL L. RUBINFELD, MICROECONOMICS 340
(6th ed. 2005).
11. Marginal cost is the increase in cost associated with an additional unit of
output. See, e.g., id. at 85.
12. Another related way to define market power is the ability to raise price by
restricting output. IIA PHILLIP E. AREEDA, HERBERT HOVENKAMP &
JOHN L. SOLOW, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 501 (2002).
13. See, e.g., WILLIAM J. BAUMOL, JOHN C. PANZAR & ROBERT D. WILLIG,
CONTESTABLE MARKETS AND THE THEORY OF INDUSTRY STRUCTURE
199-217 (1982).
14. J. NUECHTERLEIN & P. WEISER, DIGITAL CROSSROADS: AMERICAN
TELECOMMUNICATIONS POLICY IN THE INTERNET AGE 10 (2007).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT