CEO Turnover and Relative Performance Evaluation

Date01 October 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12282
Published date01 October 2015
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXX, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2015
CEO Turnover and Relative Performance
Evaluation
DIRK JENTER and FADI KANAAN
ABSTRACT
This paper shows that CEOs are fired after bad firm performance caused by factors
beyond their control. Standard economic theory predicts that corporate boards filter
out exogenous industry and market shocks from firm performance before deciding
on CEO retention. Using a hand-collected sample of 3,365 CEO turnovers from 1993
to 2009, we document that CEOs are significantly more likely to be dismissed from
their jobs after bad industry and, to a lesser extent, after bad market performance.
A decline in industry performance from the 90th to the 10th percentile doubles the
probability of a forced CEO turnover.
WHETHER TO RETAIN OR FIRE A CEO after bad stock price or accounting per-
formance is one of the most important decisions made by corporate boards.
Standard economic theory suggests that, when assessing the quality of its
CEO, the board of directors should ignore components of firm performance
that are caused by factors beyond the CEO’s control. Previous studies of the
relation between (arguably exogenous) market or industry performance and
CEO turnover find evidence that is largely consistent with this hypothesis.
However, using a larger data set that covers a more recent time period and a
better methodology, we find that CEOs are significantly more likely to be fired
after negative performance shocks to their peer group.
Specifically, using a new data set of 2,490 voluntary and 875 forced CEO
turnovers in 3,042 firms from 1993 to 2009, we document that low industry
stock returns and (to a lesser extent) low market returns increase the frequency
Dirk Jenter is at Stanford University and the National Bureau of Economic Research. Fadi
Kanaan is at Liberty Mutual Insurance. We thank an anonymous referee,Nittai Bergman, Andrew
Bernard, Franc¸ois Degeorge, Xavier Gabaix, Diego Garcia, Robert Gibbons, Jeffrey Gordon, Yaniv
Grinstein, Jarrad Harford, Li Jin, Rafael LaPorta, Jonathan Lewellen, Katharina Lewellen, Kalina
Manova, David McAdams, Todd Milbourn, Holger Mueller, Thomas Philippon, Joshua Pollet, An-
toinette Schoar, Jeremy Stein, Karin Thorburn, Joel Vanden, Eric Van den Steen, Ivo Welch,Kent
Womack, and seminar participants at MIT Sloan, the University of Illinois at Urbana–Champaign,
Dartmouth Tuck, Stanford GSB, Berkeley Haas, the University of Frankfurt, the 2006 Washing-
ton University Corporate Finance Conference, the 2006 Western Finance Association Meeting, the
2006 Caesarea Center Finance Conference, and the 2006 NBER Corporate Governance Summer
Institute for their comments and suggestions. All remaining errors are our own.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12282
2155
2156 The Journal of Finance R
of forced CEO turnovers. A decrease in the industry component of firm per-
formance from its 90th to its 10th percentile doubles the probability of a forced
CEO turnover. There is some evidence that boards partially filter industry and
especially market performance from their assessments of CEO quality, but the
filtering is too weak to remove all of the peer performance effect. We conclude
that boards allow exogenous shocks to firm performance to affect their CEO
retention decisions.
Standard agency theory shows that there are benefits to evaluating agents
on the basis of their relative performance when agents are affected by common
shocks (Holmstr¨
om (1979,1982), Diamond and Verrecchia (1982)). In most
of the theoretical literature on CEO dismissals, a corporate board learns the
quality of its CEO from firm performance and other signals. If the board’s as-
sessment of CEO quality falls below some threshold, often the expected quality
of a replacement, then the board dismisses the CEO.1Since CEO and CEO-firm
match quality are not functions of the business cycle in these models, it fol-
lows that efficient boards do not force out more CEOs in bad times than in good
times. More generally,these models hold that boards should filter all observable
exogenous shocks from firm performance before updating their assessments of
CEO quality. This prediction is strongly rejected by our empirical results, and
we conclude that the simple framework used in much of the literature does not
fully explain real-world CEO dismissals.
There are several possible explanations for why more CEOs are fired when
their peer group is not doing well, almost all of which fall into one of three
categories: First, CEOs may optimally be rewarded or punished for peer group
performance if CEOs’ actions affect peer performance, as would be the case
in an oligopolistic industry. Second, peer group performance may affect the
optimal frequency of CEO dismissals if boards receive more (or more important)
information about their CEOs in times of bad peer performance. This may be
the case because, for example, downturns change the skills required of CEOs
or downturns test skills that are otherwise unobservable.2Finally, peer group
performance may affect CEO turnover because boards do not behave optimally
and misattribute exogenous performance components to the CEO.
To shed light on why CEOs are fired less frequently when their peer group
is doing well, we examine the relationship between CEO dismissals and peer
performance in more detail. The main result of these analyses is that peer
performance has only small effects on outperforming CEOs, but large effects on
underperforming CEOs. Better peer group performance substantially reduces
the probability that an underperformer is dismissed, which implies that many
fewer underperformers are fired in good times than in bad times. This may be
optimal if underperformance in good times is less revealing about deficiencies
1See, for example, Hirshleifer and Thakor (1994,1998), Hermalin and Weisbach (1998,2003),
Wart her (1998), Adams and Ferreira (2007), and Taylor (2010).
2See Eisfeldt and Kuhnen (2013) for a model in which industry downturns are associated with
changing CEO skill requirements.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT