Cautious Risk Takers: Investor Preferences and Demand for Active Management

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12747
Published date01 April 2019
Date01 April 2019
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIV, NO. 2 APRIL 2019
Cautious Risk Takers: Investor Preferences and
Demand for Active Management
VALERY POLKOVNICHENKO, KELSEY D. WEI, and FENG ZHAO
ABSTRACT
Despite their mediocre mean performance, actively managed mutual funds are dis-
tinct from passive funds in their return distributions. Active value funds better hedge
downside risk, while active growth funds better capture upside potential. Since such
performance features may appeal to investors with tail-overweighting preferences,
we show that preferences for downside protection and upside potential estimated
from the empirical pricing kernel can help explain active fund flows in the value
and growth categories, respectively.This effect of investor risk preferences varies sig-
nificantly with funds’ downside-hedging and upside-capturing ability, with levels of
active management, and across retirement and retail funds.
DESPITE THE MEDIOCRE PERFORMANCE of actively managed mutual funds rela-
tive to their passively managed counterparts, assets under active management
continue to significantly outweigh those of index funds.1This puzzle has at-
tracted considerable interest in the mutual fund literature. While some stud-
ies attempt to rationalize investments in actively managed funds by modeling
state-dependent managerial effort or skill, in this paper we explore components
in the demand for active management that stem from investor preferences for
upside potential or downside risk protection. We show that, compared with pas-
sive benchmarks, active value funds achieve greater downside hedging while
Valery Polkovnichenko is with University of Texas at Dallas and the Federal Reserve Board
of Governors. Kelsey D. Wei and Feng Zhao are with University of Texas at Dallas. We thank
Ken Singleton (the Editor); the anonymous Associate Editor; two anonymous referees; and Angie
Andrikogiannopoulou, Jules van Binsbergen, Vincent Glode, Kris Jacobs, Rachel Pownall, and
Clemens Sialm for comments and suggestions. We also thank conference participants at the 2015
AFA conference, 2013 Lone Star Finance Symposium, 2014 FIRS annual conference, 2014 Confer-
ence on Professional Asset Management at Rotterdam School of Management, 2013 FMA Asian
Annual Meetings, 2014 Mitsui Finance Symposium at the University of Michigan, and University
of Oregon Finance Department 2014 Conference on Institutional Investors; as well as seminar par-
ticipants at American University, Central University of Finance and Economics, Federal Reserve
Board, Harbin Institute of Technology, Temple University, University of Delaware, University of
Houston, University of St. Gallen, and U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission. The views pre-
sented in this paper are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the
Federal Reserve Board or its staff. We have read the disclosure policy of the Journal of Finance
and have nothing to disclose.
1For example, Fama and French (2010) estimate that, during the 1984 to 2006 period, active
equity mutual funds underperformed benchmark portfolios by approximately 1% annually,roughly
the average cost of investing in mutual funds.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12747
1025
1026 The Journal of Finance R
active growth funds deliver stronger upside potential. We then link variation
in investor preferences to fund flows and show that proxies for investor pref-
erences have significant explanatory power for flows into actively managed
growth and value funds. These findings contribute to our understanding of
investor demand for actively managed mutual funds.
We begin by constructing bootstrapped samples of monthly returns of actively
managed mutual funds and their passive benchmarks to compare their return
distributions.2To isolate the active component of fund returns, we construct
the market-neutral excess returns of active funds over passive benchmarks.
We use the skewness of returns and excess return (idiosyncratic) skewness to
measure the upside potential of active funds. To measure downside protection
of active portfolios, we use co-skewness with market returns, downmarket
betas of excess returns, and excess returns’ loadings on aggregate jump and
volatility risk factors constructed from straddle portfolios of S&P 500 index
options (Cremers, Halling, and Weinbaum (2015), CHW henceforth).3
The results of our analysis of active fund returns and their excess returns
over passive benchmarks suggest that the return distributions of active funds
are quite different from those of their passive benchmarks in terms of their
downside-hedging and upside-capturing properties. While both active growth
and value funds possess some of these return features, their extent varies con-
siderably.On balance, active value funds provide better downside-hedging abil-
ity.Relative to passive benchmarks, active value funds have lower co-skewness
with the market, have lower downside beta, and provide significant hedging
against aggregate jump risk. On the other hand, active growth funds exhibit
more pronounced upside-capturing features. Relative to passive benchmarks,
they have considerably higher skewness and positive idiosyncratic skewness.
In addition, while their overall market beta tends to be high, active growth
funds also reduce beta during market downturns. However, unlike active value
funds, active growth funds do not provide hedging against jump risk.
In addition to using the market portfolio as the simplest benchmark, we
employ two other benchmarking methods. The first benchmark is constructed
based on holdings-matched portfolios. Relative to return-based benchmarks,
holdings-based benchmarks have the advantage of abstracting from factors af-
fecting fund returns that are unrelated to active equity investment strategies
(e.g., fees and cash reserve). In addition, they allow us to control for differences
in diversification (including number of different stocks in the portfolio) and
security characteristics between active and passive funds (Bollen and Busse
(2001), Huang, Sialm, and Zhang (2011)). To construct this benchmark, every
quarter for each active fund in our sample, we replace each of its holdings with
a randomly drawn stock with the same size, book-to-market, and momentum
(SBM) quintile ranks. The returns of this hypothetical portfolio are used as our
passive benchmark. To construct the other benchmark, we follow Berk and van
2We report results with total net-of-fee returns and equity portfolio holding gross returns using
the bootstrap procedure. Our conclusions are not affected by the type of return used.
3We thank Martijn Cremers for providing jump and volatility risk factor data.
Cautious Risk Takers 1027
Binsbergen (2015) and use four-factor model (Fama-French three factors plus
momentum) predicted returns. Regardless of the benchmark used, our results
point to consistent and marked differences in the return distribution across ac-
tive and passive funds and across different investment objectives. The distinct
properties of active fund returns cannot be explained by the potentially differ-
ent characteristics of securities held by active versus passive funds, nor can
they be attributed to lower diversification of active funds’ portfolios compared
to those of passive funds.
Given the observed differences in the returns of active versus passive funds,
we hypothesize that active funds may appeal to investors who value upside po-
tential and downside protection. While we refer to investors with such prefer-
ences by an oxymoron (“cautious risk takers”) in the title, these preferences are
widely supported by experimental evidence (Camerer and Ho (1994), Camerer
(1995), Starmer (2000)). Several theoretical models of portfolio choice demon-
strate that investors who overweight tail probabilities of return distributions
may prefer portfolio returns with limited downside risk and high upside poten-
tial.4Changes in investor expectation, risk attitude, or investor composition
would naturally generate flows in and out of different styles of funds. Based on
the distributional properties of active funds’ returns, we hypothesize that flows
into actively managed value funds increase with investor aversion to downside
risk while flows into actively managed growth funds increase with investor
preference for upside potential.
To explore whether this channel of demand for active funds is theoretically
plausible, we consider a portfolio choice problem of an investor who has access to
a risk-free asset and to active and passive funds with a joint return distribution
as bootstrapped from the data. We assume that the investor maximizes rank-
dependent expected utility (RDEU; Quiggin (1982), Yaari (1987)) with a Prelec
(1998) inverse-S probability weighting function. This weighting function has
two parameters, which allows for a variety of risk attitudes toward tail events,
including joint preferences for upside potential and downside protection.
We solve numerically for the optimal portfolios and examine the comparative
statics of the demand for active management with respect to the parameters of
the probability weighting function. Our results demonstrate that the observed
differences in return distributions between active and passive funds are quan-
titatively relevant to an RDEU investor. In particular, we show that demand
for active value funds increases when the investor has greater preference for
downside protection, while demand for active growth funds increases when the
investor exhibits greater upside-seeking preference. We also use the model to
compute the implied value of active funds and find that an investor would be
willing to pay reasonable fees for access to the active fund portfolios.
4For example, Shefrin and Statman (2000) show that such investors would construct optimal
portfolios with downside protection containing upside lottery-like security. Polkovnichenko (2005)
and Mitton and Vorkink(2007) find that investors with tail-overweighting preferences, while being
risk-averse overall, may invest in less diversified assets to increase the upside potential of portfolio
returns.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT