Can Unemployment Insurance Spur Entrepreneurial Activity? Evidence from France

AuthorDAVID SRAER,JOHAN HOMBERT,ANTOINETTE SCHOAR,DAVID THESMAR
Date01 June 2020
Published date01 June 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12880
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXV, NO. 3 JUNE 2020
Can Unemployment Insurance Spur
Entrepreneurial Activity? Evidence from France
JOHAN HOMBERT, ANTOINETTE SCHOAR, DAVID SRAER,
and DAVID THESMAR
ABSTRACT
We evaluate the effect of downside insurance on self-employment. Weexploit a large-
scale reform of French unemployment benefits that insured unemployed workers
starting businesses. The reform significantly increased firm creation without decreas-
ing the quality of new entrants. Firms started postreform were initially smaller, but
their employment growth, productivity,and survival rates are similar to those prere-
form. New entrepreneurs’ characteristics and expectations are also similar. Finally,
jobs created by new entrants crowd out employment in incumbent firms almost one-
for-one, but have a higher productivity than incumbents. These results highlight the
benefits of encouraging experimentation by lowering barriers to entry.
The problem with the French is that they have no word for entrepreneur.
Attributed to George W. Bush.
OVER THE LAST TWO DECADES, policymakers and academics alike have em-
braced the idea that reducing barriers to self-employment and entrepreneur-
ship is important for promoting job creation.1The primary focus of empirical
research has been on understanding how such barriers affect the level of en-
trepreneurial activity (i.e., the number of new firms created). Many recent stud-
ies find evidence of significant heterogeneity among potential entrepreneurs’
Johan Hombert is with HEC Paris. Antoinette Schoar is with MIT-Sloan, NBER, and CEPR.
David Sraer is with UC Berkeley, NBER, and CEPR. David Thesmar is with MIT-Sloan and
CEPR. This article is the substantially revised version of a paper previously circulated under
the title “Should the Government Make it Safer to Start a Business? Evidence From a French
Reform.” We thank participants at many conferences and seminars for comments and suggestions.
In particular, we are indebted to Ashwini Agrawal, Steve Davis, Guy Laroque, David Matsa, Toby
Moskowitz, Marina Niessner, Elena Simintzi, and Amit Seru for their valuable insights. The data
used in this paper are confidential but not the authors’ exclusive access. We have read The Journal
of Finance disclosure policy and have no conflicts of interest to disclose.
Correspondence: David Thesmar, MIT Sloan School of Management, CEPR, 100 Main Street,
Cambridge, MA 02142; e-mail: thesmar@mit.edu
1See the fast-growing literature on the impact of financial market and regulatory reforms on
entrepreneurship, for example, Bertrand, Schoar, and Thesmar (2007), Cole (2009), Djankov et al.
(2002), and Klapper, Laeven, and Rajan (2006).
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12880
C2020 the American Finance Association
1247
1248 The Journal of Finance R
ability to grow, risk tolerance, ambition, and even optimism.2In light of such
heterogeneity, the welfare implications of reducing barriers to entrepreneur-
ship become unclear, as they depend crucially on how such policies affect the
quality of new entrepreneurs. On the one hand, if individuals have private
information about their entrepreneurial abilities, lower barriers to entry may
decrease the quality of the average entrepreneur. On the other hand, reduc-
ing start-up costs can lead skilled but risk-averse individuals to enter self-
employment (Kihlstrom and Laffont (1979)) by allowing them to experiment
and learn about their ability (as in Jovanovic (1982), Caves (1998), Manso
(2011)).
In this paper, we empirically investigate how large reductions in the cost
of entry affect selection into entrepreneurship and allocative efficiency more
generally. To do so, we exploit a large-scale reform of the French unemploy-
ment insurance (UI) system that provides downside insurance to unemployed
workers starting a business. To derive testable predictions, we first develop an
equilibrium model of occupational choice that features risk-averse individuals
with heterogeneous entrepreneurial skills. Individuals decide between wage
employment or self-employment. The success of the firm is determined by a
combination of skill (known in advance) and chance. In the model, provid-
ing downside insurance to entrepreneurs increases entry, but the number and
quality of new businesses depend on the dispersion of talent. When talent is
relatively heterogeneous, decreasing downside risk has a modest effect on new
firm creation, reduces entrepreneurial quality, and leads to a smaller reduction
in the size of incumbent firms competing for the same resources. We refer to
this explanation as the selection view. In contrast, when the talent distribution
is more homogeneous, providing downside insurance has a pronounced effect
on new firm creation, a modest effect on entrepreneurial quality, and a signif-
icant crowding-out effect on incumbents. In the latter case, facilitating entry
increases allocative efficiency by allowing relatively skilled but risk-averse indi-
viduals to become entrepreneurs. Importantly,the model requires that workers
cannot engage in risk-sharing contracts with outside financiers (e.g., through
revolving credit or outside equity), so that the provision of downside insur-
ance by the UI system generates real benefits for unemployed workers. In this
sense, our model, and hence our interpretation of the data, is consistent with
the reform completing a missing insurance market (Rampini and Viswanathan
(2010)). While the provision of downside insurance may also relax new firms’
financial constraints, for example, by allowing entrepreneurs to pledge future
unemployment benefits, we reject this alternative interpretation in the data.
We empirically evaluate these trade-offs by exploiting a reform that facil-
itated the transition of unemployed individuals into self-employment—Plan
d’Aide au Retour `alEmploi(PARE). Prior to the PARE, unemployed workers
starting a business would lose all access to their UI benefits. After the reform,
2See, among others, Haltiwanger, Jarmin, and Miranda (2013), Nanda (2008), Hurst and Pugs-
ley (2011), Landier and Thesmar (2009), Holtz-Eakin, Joulfaian, and Rosen (1994a), and Schoar
(2010).
Can Unemployment Insurance Spur Entrepreneurial Activity? 1249
the UI agency filled the gap between unemployment benefits and realized en-
trepreneurial income, thereby offering temporary protection against potential
losses from entrepreneurship. We leverage firm- and individual-level admin-
istrative data to evaluate how this large-scale reform affected not only firm
creation, but also the characteristics of newly created firms and industry-wide
employment. Our identification strategy relies on the heterogeneity across in-
dustries in “exposure” to the reform. Unemployed individuals are empirically
more likely to start zero-employee firms and/or register as sole proprietorships.
Accordingly, we define exposure to the reform as the fraction of sole proprietors
among all newly created firms in an industry, where we measure this “treat-
ment intensity” in the years preceding the reform.3Our empirical strategy is
akin to a difference-in-difference analysis that compares changes in the num-
ber and characteristics of newly created firms following the adoption of PARE
across industries with different treatment intensity. Our identifying assump-
tion is that absent the reform, the dynamics of business creation would not
have been systematically related to industry treatment intensity.4
Our first empirical analysis establishes that the reform significantly boosted
new business creation by unemployed workers. Relative to the prereform pe-
riod, the registration of new firms in the postreform period is 14 percentage
points higher in industries belonging to the top quartile of treatment intensity,
relative to industries in the bottom quartile. This estimate is robust to a variety
of robustness checks, in particular to alternative definitions of treatment inten-
sity or event window and to controls for industries exposure to business cycle
shocks. We also find support for our causal interpretation of this estimate by
showing that, in the cross section of industries, the postreform increase in new
firm creation strongly correlates with the entry of unemployed entrepreneurs.
We next document that firms created in response to the reform are not of
(observable) worse quality.We first measure quality using ex post outcomes and
show that, relative to the prereform period, there are no significant changes
in failure rates, hiring rates, or growth rates of firms started after the reform
in the most versus least treated industries. Using administrative survey data,
we also measure quality using ex ante characteristics of entrepreneurs such as
education and self-reported growth expectations. We find no significant effect
of the reform on the composition of entrepreneurs’ educational backgrounds
and we find a small, positive effect on subjective growth expectations. Overall,
the evidence supports the experimentation view, whereby providing downside
insurance induces new firm creation without significantly reducing the average
quality of the new entrepreneurs.
3In Internet Appendix III, we show that our analysis is robust to defining treatment intensity as
the fraction of firms with zero employees among newly created firms in an industry. The Internet
Appendix is available in the online version of the article on The Journal of Finance website.
4We explore the validity of this assumption by conducting numerous robustness checks. In
particular, our relatively high-frequency data allow us to include industry-specific trends in the
regression analysis. Including these trends does not affect our main estimates, which provides
support for the parallel trends assumption.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT