Can consumer complaints reduce product reliability? Should we worry?

Date01 January 2020
AuthorJoaquín Coleff
Published date01 January 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12335
J Econ Manage Strat. 2020;29:7496.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems74
|
© 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Received: 11 October 2013
|
Revised: 1 October 2019
|
Accepted: 6 November 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12335
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Can consumer complaints reduce product reliability?
Should we worry?
Joaquín Coleff
1,2
1
Centro de Estudios Distributivos
Laborales y Sociales (CEDLAS), Instituto
de Investigaciones Económicas, Facultad
de Ciencias Económicas, Universidad
Nacional de La Plata, La Plata, Argentina
2
Comisión de Investigaciones Científicas
(CIC), La Plata, Argentina
Correspondence
Joaquín Coleff, Centro de Estudios
Distributivos Laborales y Sociales
(CEDLAS), Instituto de Investigaciones
Económicas, Facultad de Ciencias
Económicas, Universidad Nacional de La
Plata, Calle 6 # 777, La Plata 1900,
Argentina.
Email: jcoleff@gmail.com
Abstract
We analyze a monopolists pricing and product reliability decision in a model
where consumers are entitled to product replacement if the product fails, but
have heterogeneous costs of exercising this right. Our main result shows that,
under some conditions, a decrease in consumers expected to claim cost leads to
a decrease in product reliability but an increase in profit and welfare. This result
is robust to a number of extensions. Our results are in line with anecdotal
evidence suggesting that changes in consumersclaiming cost can be induced by
both third parties (governments, consumersorganizations, private enterprises,
etc.) and firms. More precisely, since, under some conditions, profit and welfare
align, public initiatives oriented to lower consumersclaiming cost will be
ultimately joined by firms that benefit from further increases in complaints.
KEYWORDS
consumer complaints, liability cost, product reliability, warranty
JEL CLASSIFICATION
D21; D42; K41; L10
1
|
INTRODUCTION
In the past five decades consumers have increasingly resorted to customersclaims in response to the purchase of faulty
units. Several factors may contribute to explain this observation. First, legislation has granted an increasing number of
rights to consumers. In 1962, Kennedys Administration introduced the Consumer Bill of Rights introducing, for the
first time, the rights to Safety, Choose, Be Informed, and Be Heard. Later, in 1985, additional consumer rights were
added: Satisfaction of Basic Needs, Redress, Consumer Education, and Healthy Environment. Since then, similar
legislations have been passed in most countries. Second, markets have experienced a proliferation of institutions aimed
at easing the process of complaining by consumers. Examples of these abound: small courts, class action lawsuits,
public agencies (e.g., National Highway Traffic Safety Administration [NHTSA] in the United States) and consumer
associations (e.g., Consumer Union provides information or claims on consumers behalf). At the same time,
developments in information and communication technologies (ICT) have made simpler for consumers to voice their
complaints. For example, carrelated complaints directed to NHTSA rose from dozens to thousands when email and
online complaints were first introduced in 1995. In the same way, customer engagement platforms like
getsatisfaction.com(US) or miqueja.com(Spain) provide online services to handle complaints, to mediate between
consumers and firms, and to rank firms according to the number of complaints received and the responses given to
them. Finally, firms have recently taken upon themselves to handle consumer complaints effectively; more than 40,000
firms use getsatisfaction.comin the United States.
1
In view of these trends, it is natural to ask to what extent changes
in consumersclaiming costand thus in consumerscomplaining behavioraffect product reliability, firms profit,
and welfare.
This paper studies the effects that an exogenous reduction in consumersclaiming cost has on product reliability,
private profit, and social welfare. In our model, a monopolist chooses the price and the reliability rate of the product it
manufactures. The products reliability is defined by the probability that the product is not defective. Providing a more
reliable product or replacing a faulty unit are costly actions for the firm. At the same time, increasing the products
reliability lowers the firms expected cost associated with replacements. This effect, that we termed replacement effect,
increases with the number of replacements requested.
In the benchmark model, the consumer complaining behavior is always efficient, by assuming that with some
probability a consumer is a claimant with no cost of requesting a replacement/compensation. Otherwise, the consumer
is a nonclaimant (or has an extremely high claiming cost). Consumers are heterogeneous in their valuations for the
product. Their utilities depend on whether the product turns out to be defective or not. After buying a faulty product, a
claimant files a costless complaint to pursue a replacement and a nonclaimant scraps the product.
2
We assume that
consumers only know if they are claimants or nonclaimants after purchasing a faulty product. Consumers anticipate
the expected future cost associated with defective units when calculating their willingness to pay for the product. In our
benchmark case, this cost comprises a cost associated with the disposal of defective unitsin case the consumer is
nonclaimant. We call demand effect to the effect of an increase in the products reliability on consumerswillingness to
pay. The higher the probability that the consumer is nonclaimant, the lower his willingness to pay but the larger the
demand effect. In other words, as it becomes less likely for a consumer to request a replacement, his willingness to pay
becomes more sensitive to the products reliability. For this benchmark case, a reduction in consumersclaiming cost is
represented by an increase in the likelihood of being claimant and thus, an increase in the number of claimants among
buyers.
We first show that the products reliability decreases when the number of claimants increases. This result is driven
by the impact that a reduction in the demand effect has on the incentives to provide reliability. In particular, an increase
in the likelihood of requesting a replacement of defective units decreases the demand effect by reducing the probability
of scrapping faulty units. Notice, however, that any increase in the number of claimants also increases the replacement
effect as more consumers will now request a replacement. We prove that any increase in the number of claimants
induces a reduction in the products reliability.
Second, we show that an increase in the number of claimants increases the firms profit. There are two effects when
the number of claimants increases: consumerswillingness to pay increases anticipating that is more likely they can
turn to the firm instead of scrapping the product;
3
but also the firms expected cost of replacements increases as
consumers are more likely to request replacements.
4
In the benchmark case, we show that any increase in the number
of complaints induces an increase in profit. Additionally, the firms profit and social welfare are aligned; the increase in
claimants increases the firms profit and social welfare albeit it reduces the products reliability.
In this benchmark case, reducing consumersclaiming cost and increasing the number of socially desirable
claimants are linked together by the simplifying strong assumption that claimants have always zero claiming cost. This
scenario is extended to a more complex (and realistic) case where consumers have heterogeneous claiming cost and
they choose whether to pursue a replacement of a faulty product even when it may be quite costly to do so (or even
socially undesirable). In particular, a reduction in consumersclaiming cost may increase the number of claimants but
it may decrease the firms profit; similarly, when complaints are socially undesirable, social welfare may also decrease.
Moreover, if a reduction in consumersclaiming cost that increases the number of claimants has a small impact on
increasing consumerswillingness to pay, product reliability may also increase. This may happen when the demand
effect does not decrease and there is an increase in the replacement effect due to more replacement requests.
Consequently, it is not obvious the extent of our results presented in the benchmark case. We show that the main
results still hold under mild assumptions over claiming cost distributions in the following way. We prove that when the
expected benefit a claimant obtains from requesting a replacement is high enough, any reduction in consumers
claiming cost induces an increase in the number of complaints and profit and a reduction in products reliability.
Additionally, when the benefit a claimant obtains from requesting a replacement is high enough firms profit and social
welfare are aligned; then, a decrease in consumersclaiming cost increases the firms profit and social welfare albeit
reduces products reliability.
The key assumption over distributions is to assume that when a reduction in consumersclaiming cost motivates an
increase in the number of claimants, it also reduces the expected cost of claimants; in the limit, expected claiming cost
is zero (or small). That is, the expected claiming cost to be decreasing in the number of claimants. Under this
COLEFF
|
75

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT