Brand Management and Strategies Against Counterfeits

AuthorYi Qian
Date01 June 2014
Published date01 June 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12057
Brand Management and Strategies Against
Counterfeits
YIQIAN
Kellogg School of Management
Northwestern University
2001, Sheridan Road
Evanston, IL 60208 and National Bureau of Economic Research
yiqian@nber.org
In this paper,I provide a theory for brand-protection strategies to reduce counterfeiting under weak
intellectual property rights. My theoretical framework has general implications for endogenous
sunk cost investments as a means of deterring counterfeiters. My model incorporates two layers
of asymmetric information that counterfeits can incur: counterfeiters fooling consumers and
buyers of counterfeits fooling other consumers. Brands have a number of tools at their disposal to
maintain a separating equilibrium in the face of counterfeits. One of the theoretical predictions
of this study is that counterfeit entry induces incumbent brands to introduce new products. This
helps to explain the innovation strategies that authentic firms employ in response to entry by
counterfeiters in practice. Authentic prices rise if and only if the counterfeit quality is lower than
a threshold level. In addition, the model demonstrates how authentic producers could invest in
self-enforcement to increase counterfeiters’ incentives to separate themselves from brands. Better
channel management through company stores and other costly devices are forms of nonprice
signals and complement a company’s own enforcements against counterfeits. These predictions
are validated using unique panel data collected from Chinese shoe companies covering the years
1993–2004. Data further reveal that companies with worse relationships with the government
invest more in various self-enforcement strategies, which are effective in reducing counterfeit
sales, and that the set of strategies are complements rather than substitutes for each other.
1. Introduction
Brand names have significant economic value and offer a guarantee of quality that
generic products often do not match. The inherent value that brand names carry gen-
erates incentives for imitation and counterfeiting. The World Customs Organization
(WCO, 2004) estimates that 512 billion euro’s worth of traded world merchandise may
have been counterfeits (WCO, 2004). Besides the business stealing effect that industries
have blamed counterfeits for, counterfeiting can also bring ethical costs (Gino et al.,
2010). Therefore, it is pertinent to study and propose marketing strategies that original
producers could employ to appropriately countervail counterfeits.
Demand for counterfeits has been explored to some extent in the marketing liter-
ature (Bloch et al., 1993; Wee et al., 1995; Cordell et al., 1996; Tom et al., 1998; Kwong
et al., 2003; Wilcox et al., 2009), with price, attitudes toward big branded companies, and
The author is grateful to Daniel Spulber, the anonymous coeditor and referees, and Philippe Aghion, Eric
Anderson, Kevin Bryan, Richard Caves, Anne Coughlan, Josh Lerner, and Scott Stern for helpful advice and
comments, and to Diane Culhane for copyediting. Cooperation from the Chinese Quality and Technology
Supervision Bureau (QTSB) and the companies I interviewed and surveyed is gratefully acknowledged. The
results in this paper do not necessarily represent the views of QTSB.
C2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume23, Number 2, Summer 2014, 317–343
318 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
the need for status signaling being cited as main factors driving counterfeit demand. On
the supply side, a few studies have examined the piracy network effects (Conner and
Rumelt, 1991), the legal responsibilities of firms and government (Olsen and Granzin,
1992), and the way firms’ internal organizations complement weak intellectual prop-
erty rights enforcement (Zhao, 2006). Enlightening as these studies are, the economic
impacts of counterfeits and the corresponding marketing strategies are still not fully
understood. Grossman and Shapiro (1988) discuss counterfeit impacts primarily in the
international trade setting and their theoretical predictions cannot fully explain recent
empirical findings. In particular,counterfeiters attempt to infringe upon brands and may
generate asymmetric information complexities to fool consumers. The findings in Qian
(2008) that authentic companies strive to upgrade quality and build company stores after
counterfeiters enter demonstrate the value of disentangling asymmetric information for
consumers. These strategies can also broadly be considered as endogenous sunk costs
(ESCs), a term introduced by Sutton (1991).
I build upon a vertical differentiation model (Gabszewicz and Thisse, 1979, 1980)
with endogenous quality and other ESC to analyze brand-protection strategies to counter
counterfeit entry. I introduce quality options for the authentic producer who chooses
quality according to its potential to yield higher profits. I first analyze price competition
with a given quality (one per firm) under the entry game, and then look at the ex ante
choice of quality.This endogenization of quality setting helps to resolve the counterintu-
itive observations in practice that authentic prices often rise after entry by counterfeiters
(Barnett, 2005). This study derives conditions under which quality can be used as one
of the key strategic decision variables to combat counterfeits.
In addition, I model two layers of asymmetric information that counterfeits fre-
quently generate. First, and perhaps more important, asymmetric information lies be-
tween the counterfeiter and buyers. I model this through a fraction of consumers who
cannot distinguish counterfeits from authentic goods when they are sold at the same
price. National surveys indicate that the majority of consumers who purchased counter-
feits (98% for cigars and 70% for footwear) thought they were authentic. Second, some
buyers may show off counterfeits to signal their fake status. I model such asymmetric
information among consumers by a positive probability that a consumer who wears
counterfeits cannot be discerned by others, and hence this consumer derives the full
utility on brand premium.
I take into account asymmetric information by building on the literature of qual-
ity uncertainty. Price is the conventional signal for product quality, but Nelson (1974)
points out the importance of advertising as a nonprice signal for quality. Milgrom and
Roberts (1986) argue that prices are better signals for quality than nonprice signals (no-
tably advertisements) unless repeated purchases are assumed. Moorthy and Srinivasan
(1995) propose money-back guarantees as another effective signal for quality. Despite
the sophistication of the previous literature, the models considered only a monopolis-
tic market and assumed exogenous quality levels. Since counterfeiters attempt to copy
authentic products and usually produce inferior quality, the competition is more ver-
tical in nature. Metrick and Zeckhauser (1999) use a simplified vertical differentiation
framework to model competition under asymmetric information. However, their mod-
els are still confined to exogenous quality, and they derive equilibrium market shares in
a price-pooling equilibrium, which is helpful for explaining certain sector equilibria but
not applicable to most counterfeit markets.
In sum, my model captures the defining characteristic of counterfeits, that is,
the intent to deceive, by incorporating both layers of asymmetric information pertain-
ing to counterfeits. The framework enriches the analysis of a broad set of instruments

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT