Brakes to the diffusion of a two‐sided social innovation: A case study on microinvestors' perspectives

AuthorGlòria Estapé‐Dubreuil,Arvind Ashta,Stéphan Bourcieu,Jean‐Pierre Hédou
Date01 May 2020
Published date01 May 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/jsc.2326
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Brakes to the diffusion of a two-sided social innovation: A case
study on microinvestors' perspectives
Arvind Ashta
1
| Glòria Estapé-Dubreuil
2
| Jean-Pierre Hédou
3
| Stéphan Bourcieu
1
1
Burgundy School of Business, Université
Bourgogne Franche-Comté, France
2
Universitat Autonòma de Barcelona, Spain
3
Burgundy Regional Association of CIGALES,
France
Correspondence
Arvind Ashta, CEREN, EA 7477, Burgundy
School of Business, Université Bourgogne
Franche-Comté, France.
Email: arvind.ashta@bsb-education.com
Funding information
Burgundy Franche-Comté Regional Council,
Grant/Award Numbers: PARI-2, PARI-10;
Banque Populaire
Abstract
The diffusion of social innovation requires overcoming institutional resilience and
ignorance of innovation. The forces of the marketing and development work of the
organization managers may be unable to overcome the strength of the institutional
framework. These institution brakes include soft norms such as values, ideology, and
psychology, as well as hard norms such as regulations. Spurts in the diffusion of the
innovation require exogenous crises to overcome the friction.
KEYWORDS
innovation diffusion, institutional entrepreneur, institutional work, microfinance, social
innovation
1|INTRODUCTION
Microcredit shot into prominence over the last four decades and now
has over 200 million borrowers (Reed et al., 2015) and is a significant
recipient of impact investments (JPMorgan and GIIN, 2013). The high
repayment rates of microcredit may be fostered by shame
(Karim, 2008). They may be accompanied by stress that may lead to
suicides (Ashta, Khan, & Otto, 2015), especially in situations of over-
indebtedness. For entrepreneurial microfinance to work better, we
need to lower the entrepreneurial stress from over-dependence on
debt by ushering in micro-equity.
Nevertheless, micro-equity experiments are still relatively
unknown. We examine one innovative structure providing micro-
equity to examine why it failed even though it was attempted in a
developed country. In short, we use this case study to inform the
question on why interesting and much-needed social innovations fail
to get embedded into the institutional framework.
The answer to this question provides lessons for the diffusion of
social innovations.
Our research builds on the discussion of the institutional cage
(DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; DiMaggio & Powell, 1991) and the embed-
ded agency paradox (Battilana & d'Aunno, 2009) in the relevant litera-
ture. Since our norms and beliefs bound us, we should not usually
want to make changes. However, change does occur. Institutional
researchers stress the need for institutional entrepreneurship
(Bjerregaard & Lauring, 2012; Mair & Marti, 2009; Marti &
Mair, 2009; Zimmerman & Callaway, 2001) engaged in institutional
work (Lawrence, Suddaby, & Leca, 2009a; Palmer, Simmons, Robin-
son, & Fearne, 2015) to change regulations, culture, norms, and rou-
tines. While considerable work has been done on filling institutional
voids in microcredit and other sectors in developing countries
(Khanna, Palepu, & Sinha, 2005; Mair & Marti, 2009; Mair, Marti, &
Ventresca, 2012), very few works have been done on micro-equity
and its lack of success in the developed world.
The present state of microfinance has motivated our study of a
French micro-equity club. The latter is an association of clubs of
investors who mobilize their savings to invest in local microenterprise,
whose need for equity capital is too small to interest orthodox actors
such as business angels or venture capital. In addition to providing
financial capital on a microscale, these investor clubs attempt to help
micro-entrepreneurs through the provision of their social capital. The
interaction of the investors and the entrepreneurs represents a two-
sided market, and the diffusion of social innovations may be more dif-
ficult since institutional disruption is required from both sides. Based
on this case study, we examine the dialectics of forces directed
JEL classification codes: A13, G14, G11, L26.
Our thanks to the members of CIGALES for the time they devoted to us. Our thanks to
review comments from a host of anonymous reviewers, Yann Truong, Frank De Bakker, and
participants at the Financial Inclusion in Developed Countries Mini-Conference in Dijon
(2012), 5th International Research Workshop on Microfinance Management and Governance
in Oslo (2012), and 13th FRAPFinance, Risk and Accounting Perspectives conference in
Cambridge (2013).
DOI: 10.1002/jsc.2326
Strategic Change. 2020;29:267283. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jsc © 2020 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 267
toward the development of this social innovation and the brakes of
resilience.
We find that there was a lack of disruptive institutional entrepre-
neurship (Bjerregaard & Lauring, 2012; Matthyssens, Vandenbempt, &
Van Bockhaven, 2013) to change values and beliefs. The work
required for change needs not only resources but also to dismantle
old ideas through dialectical mechanisms (Hoholm & Olsen, 2012).
Since two-sided markets and network effects (Rochet & Tirole, 2004)
are often found in social ventures (one for attracting the providers of
resources and one for attracting the target population of the
excluded), we need to alter values and beliefs on both sides of the
market.
The next section reviews the relevant literature on institutional stud-
ies and social entrepreneurship, as well as the conceptual framework that
we mobilize to answer the question of why social innovation diffusion
efforts may be insufficient to overcome institutional resilience. This
review is followed by details on the methodology and the empirical
case study. Then, our findings are presented and discussed. The
results are then used to formulate the inductive hypothesis. The final
section concludes and provides some future research directions.
2|LITERATURE REVIEW
The section critically reviews the relevant literature on institutional
entrepreneurship and social change.
2.1 |Institutional entrepreneurship, institutional
work, institutional change
Many authors emphasize the generally stable and self-strengthening
nature of institutions (Berger & Luckmann, 1986): in fact, institutions
generate behaviors among economic actors tending to reproduce and
reinforce themselves. Whitley (1999, 1992), mainly, gives a central
role to the self-regulatory mechanisms of socio-economic systems
and to mutually reinforcing institutional mechanisms. A paradoxical
vicious circle is generated (Battilana & d'Aunno, 2009): how can actors
change institutions if the actors are influenced and constrained by
existing institutions?
Institutional change has been the subject of many works (Dacin,
Goodstein, & Scott, 2002), both in terms of the processes of institu-
tional change (Holm, 1995) and the modalities of it (Fligstein & Mara-
Drita, 1996; Rao, 1998). Boxenbaum (2004) gives two possible expla-
nations of institutional change. The exogenous explanation considers
that the change occurs when an external shock alters the established
institutional order. In contrast, the endogenous approach suggests
that change emerges from the interactions caused by the players,
whether at an individual level (Zucker, 1988) or at the level of a group
of actors.
DiMaggio and Powell (1991) believe that organizations are not
unilaterally exposed to external constraints, but they also put pressure
on the institutional framework through institutional strategies
(Lawrence, 1999). Therefore, institutions are a space for action for
various organizations that can lead to changes in the rules of the game
(Chabaud, Parthenay, & Perez, 2005, p 67).
Actors likely to influence those rules are referred to as institu-
tional entrepreneurs, a term coined by DiMaggio (1988) to cover
actors who mobilize resources at their disposal to create, modify or
strengthen institutions. This concept of the institutional entrepreneur
is seen as an interpretational lens for understanding the role that
actors can play in the process of institutional transformation, or trans-
formation of a sector or industry. Many authors (Dacin et al., 2002;
Fligstein, 1997) have further developed this concept of the institu-
tional entrepreneur. The institutional entrepreneur appears primarily
as an agent of legitimacy, supporting the creation of institutions that
seem appropriate and consistent with his/her interests. Just like
Schumpeter's entrepreneur develops leadership by combining capital
and innovation to introduce new products or processes, the institu-
tional entrepreneur develops leadership by combining ideas and politi-
cal vision to add new rules which are sustainable, applicable, and more
productive.
The actors who can influence this process (forming rules of
institutional games) and shape these rules hold a form of power
(Bensedrine, 1997). The institutional entrepreneurs deploy strate-
gies and mobilize resources to act on the institutional processes
to orient existing institutions in a way that is favorable to them
or create new institutions. They may define, justify, support or
compete with rivals in their institutional projects (Scott, 1995). In
this perspective, Zimmerman and Callaway (2001) detail the
actions the institutional entrepreneurs undertake to legitimate an
industry such as setting standards and/or to establish the overall
structure.
The work of these institutional entrepreneurs, termed institu-
tional work, is described as the purposive action of individuals and
organizations aimed at creating, maintaining, and disrupting institu-
tions (Lawrence, Suddaby, & Leca, 2009b). This work could include
changes in regulations (Peton & Pezé, 2014) or justifying for continua-
tion through confirmation work, qualification process, and immuniza-
tion of compromises (Taupin, 2012). One complication to studying
institutional work (as we do in this paper) is that the creation and
development of new institutions evidently require disrupting existing
institutions and stakeholders (Marti & Mair, 2009). Any study requires
finding out the agenda of competing institutions and their competing
logics (Besharov & Smith, 2014; Friedland & Alford, 1991; Thornton,
Ocasio, & Lounsbury, 2012), and ways in which collaboration can be
induced (Zietsma & McKnight, 2009). A second complication is that
within the newly created institutions, there are diverse stakeholder
interests to be managed and the institutional entrepreneur has to take
these into account (Kraatz, 2009).
Since the diffusion of social innovation requires creating new
arrangements in society, it requires institutional work at macro, meso,
and micro levels if it is to be successfully diffused (van Wijk, Zietsma,
Dorado, de Bakker, & Martí, 2018).
268 ASHTA ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT