Behavioral criminology and public policy

Published date01 November 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1745-9133.12465
Date01 November 2019
AuthorThomas A. Loughran
DOI: 10.1111/1745-9133.12465
RESEARCH ARTICLE
BEHAVIORAL CRIMINOLOGY
Behavioral criminology and public policy
Thomas A. Loughran
Pennsylvania State University
Correspondence
ThomasA. Loughran, Depar tment of Sociology
andCr iminology,Pennsylvania State Univer-
sity,1011 Oswald Tower,University Park, PA
16802.
Email:t al47@psu.edu
Iwish to thank Holly Nguyen, Justin Pickett,
SarahTahamont, Bob Apel, Shawn Bushway,
PilarLar roulet, Greg Pogarsky,Volkan Topalli,
DanNagin, and all of the par ticipants in atten-
danceat t he 2018 Symposium on Criminal
JusticeDecision-Making in Social and Legal
Contextat SUNY Albany for helpful comments.
Research Summary: Public policy, including crime pol-
icy, is heavilyshaped by economic theory. Recently, refine-
ments based on the application of behavioral insights into
the study of public policy applications have become en
vogue. Although criminologists have made some inroads
into incorporating behavioral principals into the study of
crime and offender decision-making, these contributions
have mainly been limited to the area of risk. In this arti-
cle, I offer a more widespread description of how behav-
ioral economics (BE) can be applied to the study of offender
decision-making and crime policy. Specifically, I focus on
several main areas that move beyond the traditional foci
on perceptions of risk: intertemporal choice, criminal labor
supply, mental accounting and consumption, and social
preferences. For each topical area, I first identify a presum-
able, normative model that could reasonably be drawn from
traditional rational choice theory. I then describe ways,
based on existing contributions from BE, that scholars have
sought to make the assumptions (and anomalies) of this
model more realistic.
Policy Implications: The primary aim of this article is to
highlight implications to theory and policy that increase the
utilization of BE by criminologists.
KEYWORDS
behavioral economics, offender decision-making, rational choice
More than evercr iminologists areinterested in more than just ‘rational choice’ theory, but
atheory of offender decision-making. What would a theory of offender decision-making
Criminology & Public Policy. 2019;18:737–758. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/capp © 2019 American Society of Criminology 737
738 LOUGHRAN
look like? What would its assumptions be, what would its main theoretical constructs be,
and what would its hypotheses consist of? Finally, what empirical support is there for a
theory of offender decision making and do you think such a theory would be a substan-
tively important contribution to the field?
—Recent University of Maryland comprehensive exam question, submitted by
Ray Paternoster
Public policy, whether we criminologists choose to admit it or not, is heavily shaped by economic
theory or, more specifically, by predictions about how individuals will make choices in response to
various (dis)incentives. For instance, we routinely enact and debate policies based on theoretically
derived expectations regarding how individual actors will make choices about things ranging from
saving for retirement to selecting health-care plans to choosing to which schools to send their children
based on economic theory. As Cook, Machin, and Mastrobuoni (2015) pointed out, crime policy—
particularly in the United States—is no exception to this general rule. For instance, Durlauf and Nagin
(2011) noted that the tremendous rise in U.S. incarceration rates over the past 40+years is congruent
with a theoretical framework outlined earlyon by Becker (1968). Even critics who have called attention
to the ineffectiveness of policies such as mass incarceration and zero tolerance in reducing crime still
tend to emphasize the role of other types of incentives in alternative crime control strategies such as
increased certainty, swiftness, and fairness (Kennedy, 2009; Kleiman, 2009; Durlauf & Nagin, 2011;
Nagin, Solow, & Lum, 2015).
That said, there is a limit to the effectiveness of designing policies strictly around the assumptions
that human actors always make choices that in are in their best interests, an assumption often criticized
on the basis of the limits of human rationality (Simon, 1955, 1978). For example, Thaler and Sunstein
(2003, p. 176) offered that, “Research by psychologistsand economists over the past three decades has
raised questions about the rationality of the judgments and decisions that individuals make.” As a result,
a growing movement to incorporate insights from behavioral economics (BE) to generate refinements
into the study of public policy applications has become en vogue worldwide (Madrian, 2014). Akerlof,
Oliver, and Sunstein (2017, p. 1, emphasis added) described this emergent ideological shift as follows:
“There are many indications of the growth in what may be broadly classified as behavioural pub-
lic policy.”1This new increased emphasis on incorporating behavioral science principles into public
policy has been widely embraced by many areas, including health policy (Hallsworth, 2016), environ-
mental policy (Carlsson & Johansson-Stenman, 2012; Venkatachalam,2008), accounting and financial
regulation (Hirshleifer, Huang, & Teoh, 2017), and the study of substance use disorders (Bickel et al.,
2014).
It is only natural then that this domain of thinking should also move into the study of crime policy.
Yet to date, with some notable exceptions (Pickett, 2018; Pogarsky & Loughran, 2016; Pogarsky,
Roche, & Pickett, 2018), there remain few active advancements as to how behavioral economics can
more fully inform the study of crime and policies aimed at crime prevention. Darley and Alter (2013,
p. 181) argued that, “[C]onventional approaches to dealing with crime, punishment, and deterrence in
the legislative policy arenas deviate from what research on behavioral decision making has recently
discovered about how people actually think and behave.” There are several reasons why this might
be the case. First, many criminologists have either a limited or a lack of exposure to BE, including
generally lacking understanding of its careful genesis and development through the documenting
of observed anomalies from standard economic models. Second, we as criminologists rely on a
rudimentary conceptualization of theoretical models of how offenders make choices, stemming from a
static conceptualization of rational choice theory. To embrace BE more fully, we must first expand our

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT