Banks and Corporate Decisions: Evidence from Business Groups

Date01 September 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/fima.12214
AuthorHuong N. Higgins
Published date01 September 2018
Banks and Corporate Decisions:
Evidence from Business Groups
Huong N. Higgins
Banks who can influence clients’ governance may steer those clients into mergers to reduce
the banks’ own risk. Empirical evidence based on Japan’s mergers and acquisitions (M&As)
during the country’s 1990s banking crisis indicates that acquirers with stronger bank ties made
acquisitions that they would not have normally made. These acquirerslost more shareholder value
via mergers than acquirers with weaker bank ties. The banks’ risk wasreduced, while the banks’
shareholders gained significant excess returns from their borrowers’ mergers. This paper offers
implications for corporate governance of firms with strong bank ties and advances the existing
knowledge on business groups.
This paper is motivated by the prevalence of business groups around the world and the im-
portance of banks at the center of many of them. The literature presents a range of perspectives.
Finance research via agency theory often views business groups as a mechanism to reduce agency
costs by circumventing problems associated with information asymmetries (Hoshi, Kashyap, and
Scharfstein, 1990; Prowse, 1990) or, contrarily, as a tunneling mechanism that increases agency
costs by enabling controlling shareholders to expropriate minority shareholders (Bae, Kang, and
Lee, 2002, 2006; Morck and Nakamura, 2005; Jiang, Lee, and Yue,2010). Management research
via organization theory views business groups as social and resource networks to prop up member
firms through tough times (Khanna and Palepu, 2000; Guillen, 2000; Chang and Hong, 2000;
Hoskisson et al., 2004). Risk sharing is one function often attributed to business groups (Khanna
and Yafeh, 2005). An emerging theme in the literature theorizes that business groups exist for
coinsurance (Jia, Shi, and Wang, 2013) as member firms in distress receive support from the
parent firm of the group and, in return, member fi rms contribute to the parent firm when the
latter is in distress.
Coinsurance is a term that denotes the spreading of risk among multiple parties, for example
via taking turns propping each other up (Jia et al., 2013), trading favors (Fisman and Wang, 2010),
smoothing incomes and reallocating money from one to another (Khanna and Yafeh, 2005), cross
subsidizing the weaker ones (Ferris, Kim, and Kitsabunnarat, 2003), or merging together (Kim
and McConnell, 1977). In the case of merger, coinsurance stems from financial diversification
and deployment of slack. Financial diversification results from the imperfectly correlated cash
flows of the merging firms, which reduces the bankruptcy risk of the total diversified firm
A prior version of this paper has benefited from comments by Karan Bhanot, Oyvind Bohren, Larry Brown, Froystein
Gjesdal, Don Herrmann, Jun-Koo Kang, KojiKojima, Dimitri Koutmos, Erlend Kvaal, John-Christian Langli, Kankana
Mukherjee, Mattias Nilsson, Oghenovo Obrimah, Katsuhiko Okada, David Reeb, Bill Stammerjohan, Cindy Yoshiko
Shirata, Susumu Tokusaki, Wayne Thomas, Takashi Yaekura, Noriaki Yamaji, and participants in meetings sponsored
by Kwansei Gakuin University, Louisiana Polytechnic University, the Norwegian School of Economics and Business
Administration (NHH), the Norwegian Schoolof Management (BI), and the Washington Area Finance Association. Data
collection assistance by Madhurima Bhutkar, Ann Chen, Sunny Khan, Tony Lu, Divya Tandon, and Jinjin Yu is much
appreciated.
Huong N.Higgins is a Professor in the Robert A. Foisie Schoolof Business at Worcester PolytechnicInstitute in Worcester,
MA 01609.
Financial Management Fall 2018 pages 679 – 713
680 Financial Management rFall 2018
(Levy and Sarnat, 1970; Lewellen, 1971; Higgins and Schall, 1975). Deployment of slack is
the notion that postmerger, slack from the acquirer is deployed to fulfill the target’s obligations
or to redeem the target’s nonperforming loans (Myers and Majluf, 1984; Bruner, 1988). When
one firm’s slack is tapped to cover deficiencies in the other, the risk of the total merged firm is
reduced.
This paper seeks to advance the existing knowledge on business groups by using the bank
perspective to highlight bank influence as both coinsurance and agency factors that should be
considered when studying business groups. Banks play a vital role in a large number of business
groups. In the bank perspective, the strategy, governance, and operations of group firms serve
as risk mitigation for banks at the group’s center. Risk mitigation for banks sometimes means
propping up group firms if the bank’s interest is aligned with the firm’s, but oftentimes this
alignment is not perfect or does not exist.
Specifically, this paper examines banks’ incentive to create coinsurance by steering firms
into mergers. It is typically difficult to observe the impact of banks on firms’ merger activity
as mergers necessitate approval by top stakeholders. In firms that are governed by shareholder
interest, acquisitions that do not enhance shareholder value tend to be disapprovedby shareholders.
Thus, the bank’s directive is often not sufficient for a merger. As a result, the prior literature has
little systematic evidence of bank-led mergers. However, for firms that are strongly influenced
by banks or that are members of bank-centered business groups, banks have the ability to steer
firms. Using data from Japan, where business groups have existed in various forms for centuries
and banks have a strong role in the economy, this paper contributes the first systematic evidence
of banks’ steering firms into mergers for coinsurance.
This paper uses the period 1990-2004, when Japan’s banking sector deteriorated precipitously
(as shown by Japan’s Bank Index depicted in Figure 1). Systematic banking trouble prompted
tougher prudential regulations, which pressured banks to reduce their risk and increase their
coinsurance incentive. This period is and will remain of special interest to researchers who
study capital adequacy regulations and their effects. Moreover, this period is also interesting as
during this time, a large number of Japanese banks were on the verge of noncompliance after
accumulating colossal nonperforming loans. These banks could no longer “evergreen” loans
due to tightened banking supervision, while noncompliant banks could not borrow from their
central banks and were promptly subject to regulatory action. Consequently, meeting capital
requirements became most urgent for these banks, creating a strong coinsurance incentive for
them.
Capital adequacy regulations require that banks’ ratio of capital to risk-weighted assets (hence-
forth “capital adequacy ratio”) stay at or above the specified minimum threshold. Thus, non-
performing loans pose a substantial problem to banks as they reduce loan loss reserves and,
consequently, reduce regulatory capital. Therefore, nonperforming loans exert huge regulatory
costs if banks are already on the verge of noncompliance with the capital requirements. There are
various ways for troubled banks to still clear the regulatory hurdle. One is to issue new equity.
However, this tactic is costly due to asymmetric information involving investors, banks, and bor-
rowers. A second way is to allocate the asset portfolio away from commercial loans, which have
a 100% risk weight, to assets such as risk-free government bonds of Organisation for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries, which have0% risk weight (Watanabe, 2005).
Particularly, banks use the traditional bank-led restructuring of distressed firms, which involves
selling off the firms’ assets. However,these sell-offs may not work due to tight bank-firm alliances
or an insufficient recovery of cash to pay back the bank loans. A third and more advantageous
method of restructuring loans to a troubled borrower is to arrange its acquisition by another
client who has unused resources (slack). Postmerger,acquirer slack may be tapped (e.g., through
Higgins rBanks and Corporate Decisions 681
Figure 1. Japan’s Bank Index
Source: Datastream
-4%
-2%
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
Japan's GDP Growth in%
Japan's Bank Index in Million Yen
Market Value of Japan's Bank Index in Million Yen
Japan's GDP Growth in %
liquidation or collaterization) to redeem bank loans to the distressed target.1Thus, banks es-
sentially shift their target loan risk to the acquirer shareholders. Separate from loan redemption
postmerger, financial diversification resulting from joining the merger firms’ cash flows reduces
the default risk of the total merged firm. Overall, banks, especially those on the verge of noncom-
pliance with capital requirements, have the incentive to facilitate a merger between a slack-rich
acquirer and a nonperforming target because of two reasons: first, banks may restructure target
loans with acquirer slack postmerger, thereby improving the bank’s capital adequacy ratio; and
second, a merger creates a financially diversified firm that reduces loan default risk and helps
prevent the bank’s capital adequacy ratio from worsening.
Despite their coinsurance incentive, banks do not usually have the ability to bypass a firm’s
governance to steer them into merger. However, there are a couple of exceptions. First, a bank’s
ability to steer is improvedif they are lenders to both potential merger f irms. This position provides
banks with proprietary knowledge of and access to both the acquirer and the target of a tentative
merger deal (Ivashina et al., 2009). Then, the bank can initiate interest and mediate negotiation
1A merger, by definition, folds one corporation (the target) into another (the acquirer). The target ceases to exist and the
acquirer assumes all assets and liabilities of the target. Without a merger,even if banks control or influence the separate
firms, they have far less flexibility in reducing their loan risk. This is because the legal status of corporations allows
separate firms to have separate limited liabilities, and it allows each firm to cover its disaster with its own assets. The
cost of the limited liability status to debt holders is elaborated by Leland (2007).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT