Bait and ditch: Consumer naïveté and salesforce incentives

Date01 January 2020
AuthorAntonio Rosato,Fabian Herweg
Published date01 January 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12336
© 2019 The Authors. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
J Econ Manage Strat. 2020;29:97121. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems
|
97
Received: 20 December 2018
|
Revised: 8 August 2019
|
Accepted: 7 November 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12336
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Bait and ditch: Consumer naïveté and salesforce incentives
Fabian Herweg
1
|
Antonio Rosato
2
1
Faculty of Law, Business, and
Economics, University of Bayreuth,
Bayreuth, Germany
2
Economics Discipline Group, University
of Technology Sydney, Sydney, NSW,
Australia
Correspondence
Fabian Herweg, Faculty of Law, Business,
and Economics, University of Bayreuth,
D95440 Bayreuth, Germany.
Email: fabian.herweg@uni-bayreuth.de
Funding information
Australian Research Council,
Grant/Award Number: DE180100190
Abstract
We analyze a model of price competition between a transparent retailer and a
deceptive one in a market where a fraction of consumers is naïve. The
transparent retailer is an independent shop managed by its owner. The
deceptive retailer belongs to a chain and is operated by a manager. The two
retailers sell an identical base product, but the deceptive one also offers an add
on. Rational consumers never consider buying the addon while naïve ones can
be talkedinto buying it. By offering the manager a contract that pushes him to
never sell the base good without the addon, the chain can induce an
equilibrium in which both retailers obtain morethancompetitive profits. The
equilibrium features price dispersion and market segmentation, with the
deceptive retailer targeting only naïve consumers whereas the transparent
retailer serves only rational ones.
KEYWORDS
addon pricing, bait and switch, consumer naïveté, incentive contracts
JEL CLASSIFICATION
D03; D18; D21; L13; M52
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Many consumers are familiar with socalled baitandswitch strategies whereby customers are first baitedby
merchantsadvertising of products or services at a low price but, upon visiting the store, are then pressured by
salespeople to consider similar, but more expensive, items (switching). In a series of articles appeared in the The
Haggler”—a column in the Sunday edition of The New York Times (NYT)journalist David Segal describes a somewhat
different strategy employed by large retailers like Staples, BestBuy, and others, which he dubs baitandditch: escorting
shoppers out of the store, emptyhanded, when its clear they have no intention of buying an expensive warranty or
some other addon for some steeply discounted electronic appliancea practice that employees at Staples themselves
call walking the customer.He further reports that clerks and sales representatives, at Staples and elsewhere, are
under enormous pressure to sell warranties and accessories, particularly on computers. For motivation, close tabs are
kept on the amount of extras and service plans sold for each and every computer; the goal is to sell an average of $200
worth of addons per machine, and a sales clerk who cannot achieve the goal is at risk of termination. Therefore, sale
representatives prefer to forgo the sale altogether, rather than selling the base good without the addon.
1
In the last few years there has been a dramatic increase in the sale of addon products such as extended warranties,
service plans, credit insurance, and financing programs like buy now, pay laterarrangements, and it is well known
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits use, distribution and reproduction in any medium, provided
the original work is properly cited.
that such practices generate a substantial fraction of retailersprofits in different consumer industries. Likewise, the use
of sales quota to motivate sales representatives is not novel nor is the fact that meeting ones quota is usually an
attractive goal as it leads to additional benefits such as promotion or job security (see Oyer, 2000). Yet, the NYT article
highlights how retail chains design compensation schemes that push their salespeople to target and exploit naïve or less
savvy consumers, concluding that such compensation schemes might backfire in the end.
2
Indeed, it is well known that
often salespeople successfully gameincentive systems by taking actions that increase their pay but hurt the objectives
of their employer, such as manipulating prices, influencing the timing of customer purchases, and varying effort over
their firmsfiscal years.
3
In this paper, we look at the interplay between employeescompensation schemes and market competition when
(some) consumers are naïve. We start from the same premise as the NYT articlethat firmsattempts to exploit
consumer naïveté might lead them to design somewhat perverse incentive contractsand show that a firm, by using
these seemingly perverse incentive contracts, is able to increase its profits. In particular, our analysis shows that it may
be optimal for a retailer to design a compensation scheme that incentivizes its salesforce to exclusively target naïve
consumers. The reason is that the contract between the retailer and its salesforce acts as a credible commitment device
ensuring that the retailer will not attempt to capture the whole market. This, in turn, induces other retailers in
the market to price less aggressively, thereby softening price competition.
Our baseline model is one of price competition between a transparent retailer and a deceptive one. The transparent
retailer is an independent local shop managed by its owner. The deceptive retailer is a franchise retailer which belongs
to a chain and is operated by an agent (or manager) on behalf of the chain company. The two retailers sell an identical
base product, but the deceptive retailer also offers an addon. There is a unit mass of consumers with heterogeneous
willingness to pay for the base good. Consumers can be either sophisticated or naïve. A sophisticated consumer
understands that the addon offered by the deceptive retailer is worthless. A naïve consumer, on the other hand, can be
convinced by the agent that the addon increases the value of the base good; that is, s/he can be talkedinto buying the
addon next to the base product. Our main contribution is to show that by designing an appropriate compensation
scheme for its agent, the chain can induce a pricing equilibrium in which both retailers obtain abnormalprofits; that
is above competitive levels. The chain can achieve this outcome by offering its agent a contract that pushes him to never
sell the base good without the addon. In this case, we say that the chain is engaging in baitandditchby inducing the
agent not to serve those consumers who do not wish to buy the addon. Hence, complete market segmentation arises in
equilibrium with the deceptive retailer targeting only naïve consumers while the transparent retailer serves only
rational ones. Market segmentation softens price competition and eliminates the incentives for the retailers to undercut
each others price for the base good. Moreover, we also show that the transparent retailer might obtain a higher profit
than the deceptive one. Hence, our analysis implies that even transparent firms may strictly prefer not to educate naïve
consumers, even when education is costless.
The idea that contractual delegation to an agent can be profitable for firmsowners is not new. Several authors (e.g.,
Fershtman, 1985; Fershtman & Judd, 1987; Sklivas, 1987; Vickers, 1985) have shown how, by using an appropriate
incentive contract, a firm can commit to behaving more (or less) aggressively than it would without delegation. In
particular, a firm may use seemingly perverse incentive schemes. For instance, Fershtman and Judd (1987) showed how
owners can benefit by inducing their managers to keep sales low.
4
Our paper differs from these previous contributions
in the assumed market structure and, more important, in how we model consumer behavior. These different underlying
assumptions generate novel results and implications. For example, in our model contractual delegation to an agent
provides the retail chain with a credible commitment device to serve only one kind of consumer; this, in turn, allows for
the existence of an equilibrium whereby the market is completely segmented. Moreover, our model predicts dispersion
in the base goods price despite the fact that retailers supply identical products and have the same costs. Classical
models of price dispersion (e.g., Salop & Stiglitz, 1977; Varian, 1980) rely on the presence of significant search costs for
consumers and on price randomization on the part of firms. In our model, instead, consumers are all perfectly informed
about the price(s) of the base good and the pricing games equilibrium is in pure strategies. Nonetheless, price
dispersion arises as a byproduct of the endogenous market segmentation.
The finding that the chain can increase its profits by committing to sell only the bundle isat first glance
reminiscent of the leverage theory of tied sales (Whinston, 1990). According to this theory, bundling is beneficial for the
firm that offers both products but hurts the profits of the competitor who offers only one product. By contrast, in our
model, both firms obtain higher profits if the chain commits to sell the base good only together with the addon.
Therefore, our finding that the deceptive retailer can increase its profits by committing to serve only naïve consumers,
who buy the addon together with the base good, is more similar to the role of technological bundlingas a tool to
98
|
HERWEG AND ROSATO

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT