Avoiding inheritance taxes in family firms

AuthorHojong Shin
Published date01 December 2020
Date01 December 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/fima.12308
DOI: 10.1111/fima.12308
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Avoiding inheritance taxes in family firms
Hojong Shin
College of Business, California State University,
LongBeach, Long Beach, California
Correspondence
HojongShin, College of Business, California State
University,Long Beach, 1250 N Bellflower Blvd,
LongBeach, CA 90815.
Email:hojong.shin@csulb.edu
Abstract
This article documents a novel wayto transfer control in family firms
while avoiding inheritance taxes: intragroup mergers. I provide evi-
dence that avoiding inheritance taxesis the motivation behind intra-
group mergers in Korea. In 1999, Korea initiated a tax reform that
bumped up personal inheritance taxes by 25 percentage points. In
the posttax-reform period, I find that family firms increase stock-for-
stock intragroup mergers involving targets owned by heirs. Specifi-
cally, firms with heavy inheritance taxesacquire affiliates owned by
heirs, who then convert private target shares into acquirer shares
while avoiding inheritance taxes.
1INTRODUCTION
In exchangefor these financial contributions, prosecutors say,Ms. Choi colluded with Ms. Park to ensure government
backing for several deals, most notably a controversial merger of two Samsung affiliates in 2015 that helped Mr.Lee
consolidate his hold over Samsung Electronics. The merger changed Samsung’s intricate cross-holding structure and,
prosecutors said, allowed Mr. Leeto avoid a steep inheritance-tax bill as he sought to succeed his father at the top of
the conglomerate (WallStreet Journal, August 25, 2017).1
This anecdote illustrates how,i n practice,family firms indirectly transfer control to heirs through intragroup merg-
ers.2When controlling families transfer their control through direct ownership inheritance, heirs must pay an inheri-
tance tax. This is generally what we expect when talking about transferring control in family firms. However, because
of the heavy inheritance taxes, heirs are exposedto ownership dilution risk. Thus, controlling families are incentivized
to minimize inheritance taxes to ensure that the heirs maintain sufficient control over the entire business group. A
common strategy to avoidheavy inheritance taxes is for family firms to acquire smaller affiliates owned by heirs. Then,
the heirs convert the target shares into acquirer shares. Throughthis stock-for-stock intragroupmerger,3heirs obtain
large controlling stakes in a keystrategic firm owned by the controlling family while avoiding the inheritance tax.
c
2020 Financial Management Association International
1Eun-Young Jeong, “Samsung Heir Lee Jae-Yong Convicted of Bribery, Gets Five Years in Jail,” Wall Street Journal (August 25, 2017), https://www.wsj.
com/articles/samsung-heir-lee-jae-yong-convicted-of-bribery-1503642785.
2Theintragroup merger between two Samsung group affiliates is detailed in Appendix B.
3Becauseheirs’ shares are converted into acquirers’ shares, any intragroup merger that uses cash as payment should be irrelevant.
Financial Management. 2020;49:1051–1082. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/fima 1051
1052 SHIN
Family firms comprise more than 80% of firms worldwide,4and succession largely determines their fate. Only 30%
of family firms last into a second generation, 12% into a third, and 3% into a fourth generation or beyond.5Given
the importance of succession in family firms, it has attracted significant attention in the recent literature.6However,
there is scant evidence documenting the effect of personal inheritance tax on family succession and its implications for
control-transfer processes in family firms. I fill this gap by studying one wayto transfer control: intragroup mergers.
Using a natural experiment, I provide causal evidence that avoiding inheritance taxes is the motivation behind
intragroup mergers. This natural experiment exploits Korea’s major tax reform initiativeundertaken in 1999, which
suddenly increased the maximum personal inheritance tax rate by 25 percentage points. Exploiting this unexpected
increase in inheritance taxes and using a difference-in-differences (DiD) estimation, I examine how firms respond to
the tax change when transferring control shares. Specifically,I compare how firms with high and low expected tax bur-
dens before the 1999 tax reform use intragroup mergers to transfer control shares after the tax reform. My findings
shed light on (a) the inheritance tax-savingbenefits of controlling families,(b) the transaction costs of intragroup merg-
ers, and (c) the way the overallownership structure of family firms is rebalanced.
The final data comprise 2,422 firm-year observations from the 24 largest Korean chaebols7from 1997 to 2004
(sample years). I use Korean chaebol data because Koreanchaebols have reported highly detailed interfirm ownership
information among their affiliates to the Korean Fair TradeCommission (KFTC) since the mid-1990s. Public access to
this type of information is limited in most countries but is available in Korea.8Giventhat family ownership is prevalent
around the world, my results haveimportant implications for many countries in addition to Korea.9
I first document that the number of stock-for-stock intragroup mergers increases with personal tax burdens. Next,
using the 1999 tax reform, I estimate the causal effect of the expected inheritance taxes on intragroup mergers. The
results show that the difference in intragroup mergers between firms with high and low personal inheritance taxes is
2.3 times more likelyto increase after the tax shock. I also find that among firms with high tax burdens, stock-for-stock
intragroup mergers are concentratedin (a) central firms,10 (b) firms located in the upper layer of the pyramid,11 and (c)
firms within a circular ownership chain, that is, firms where heirs can consolidate their indirect control over the entire
businessgroup. This result highlights that the ownership network of group affiliates determines which firms with heavy
inheritance taxes initiate intragroupmergers. However, this result does not hold for non-intragroup mergers.
4Chase Peterson-Withorn, “New Report Reveals the 500 Largest Family-Owned Companies in the World,” Forbes (April 20, 2015), https://www.forbes.
com/sites/chasewithorn/2015/04/20/new-report-reveals-the-500-largest-family-owned-companies-in-the-world/#6eccd1423602.
5FamilyBusiness Alliance, http://www.fbagr.org/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=117&Itemid=75(accessed June 2014).
6Pérez-González(2006) and Bennedsen, Nielsen, Pérez-González, and Wolfenzon (2007) document that family chief executive officers (CEOs) perform worse
than nonfamily CEOs. Mehrotra,Morck, Shim, and Wiwattanakantang(2013) also show that firms run by nonbiological heirs outperform firms run by either
biological heirs or professional managers. Bunkanwanicha, Fan, and Wiwattanakantang (2013) show that a network marriage between a controlling family
memberand a member of a prominent business or political family is followed by increasing stock prices.
7Family-ownedlarge business conglomerates in Korea are generally called “chaebols.”
8KFTCrequires only select Korean chaebols to divulge their ownership status information. Because of limited access to ownership data, the sample does not
includesmaller business groups.
9Theliterature shows that controlling families siphon resources out of member firms for their private benefit (Johnson, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, & Shleifer,
2000). Similar tax-saving tactics likely benefit controlling families in other institutional contexts. For example,Asian casino king Stanley Ho implemented
similarintragroup transactions to avoid inheritance taxes.
10These companies are connected to many other member firms in the ownership network. Therefore, the controlling family can indirectly control affiliated
firmsthrough strategic firms in a pyramidal business group. Following Almeida, Park,Subrahmanyam, and Wolfenzon (2012), the centrality of firm iis measured
asthe average percentage difference in the control rights of the controlling family across all group member firms except the firm itself after excludinga specific
firmifrom the group. In this article, I refer to firms with a high centrality value as “central firms.”
11The upper layer of the pyramid is an indicator that equals 1 if a firm’s position is smaller than the average of all chaebol firms, and 0 otherwise. Position
refers to the distance between the controlling family and a firm in the group. A value of 1 indicates that the firm is directly controlled bythe founding family.
In a simple pyramidstructure with two firms, firm iin the upper layer (Chain 1) has a position value of 1, and firm jin the lower layer (Chain 2) has a position
value of 2. In this case, the position of firm ican be measured by the weighted averageof Chains 1 and 2, whose importance is weighted by the cash flow the
familyreceives. Cash flow comprises direct cash flow from firm iand indirect cash flow from firm jthrough Chain 2. Group firms that are directly owned by the
controllingfamily have a low position value, whereas those that are indirectly owned have a high position value. See Almeida et al. (2012) for additional details
aboutownership metrics.
SHIN 1053
Next, I test whether a reduction in personal taxes decreases intragroup merger activities. I find that intragroup
mergers are rarely pursued by firms that have heavy inheritance taxes and are indirectly owned by private founda-
tions exempt from gift taxes.A difference-in-difference-in-differences (DiDiD) estimation of Korea’s 1999 tax reform
confirms that unusual surges in stock-for-stock intragroup mergers occur primarily because firms aim to avoid inheri-
tance taxes through intragroup mergers.12 I find that this sudden increase in intragroupmergers after the tax reform
is not prompted by the Asian financial crisis. In other words, it is not due to the sudden drop in Korea’s capital market
value during the precrisis era or postcrisis restructuring.
Furthermore,I investigate ownership reallocation by identifying target firm characteristics in relation to intragroup
mergers. I find that heirs of chaebol families receive large dividends from their private firms in which they have large
ownership stakes. These firms become the targets of intragroupmergers. Heirs can take these dividends because they
have substantial voting rights, which they use to determine corporate policies in target merger firms. Because heirs
own only their target firms that are merged with central firms, they prefer short-term wealth gains over long-term
investment commitments. However,this behavior is not necessarily found in male relatives in the current chair’s gen-
eration,for whom succession process has officially ended. Overall, these results suggest that to avoid inheritance taxes,
heirs first prefer to own private firms where they can cash out corporate resources quickly and then reallocate their
ownership to central firms through intragroupmergers.
Although controlling-family heirs are likely to benefit from this reshuffling, the ownership network becomes more
distorted as central firms expand their boundaries with additional circular shareholding links. Minority shareholders
suffer losses from these tax-motivated mergers, which have few operational synergies. Forinstance, the 2-day cumu-
lative abnormal return (CAR)drops 32.3% more when an intragroup merger is announced than when a non-intragroup
merger is announced. Overall, this evidencesupports the tunneling view of business groups discussed i nthe literature
(e.g., Johnson et al. 2000).
This article is related to several strands of literature, including studies on the effect of taxeson firms. Early stud-
ies emphasize the effects of corporate income taxes on the right-hand side of the balance sheet, such as capital
structure (Miller, 1988; Modigliani & Miller,1958, 1963) and dividend policy (Auerbach, 1979; Bradford, 1981; King,
1974). Recent studies explore topics such as the effects of tax reforms on organizational forms (Desai & Hines,
1999; Desai, Foley, & Hines, 2004) and the effects of inheritance laws on investment decisions (Ellul, Pagano, &
Panunzi, 2010; Tsoutsoura, 2015). My article connects these two recent topics by exploring ownership networks
among group affiliates. Ownership networks are a key component of the inheritance tax channels through which
firms with heavy inheritance taxes initiate intragroup mergers, which in turn cause distortions in the ownership
network.
My findings also contribute to the literature on tunneling in emerging markets. Tunneling is more prevalent in
emerging economies, where controlling shareholders exercise their discretionary power to extract private benefits
by transferring assets and profits out of firms (Johnson et al., 2000). The literature documents tunneling in business
groups under a pyramidal ownership structure by highlighting conflicts of interest between controlling shareholders
and minority shareholders (Almeida & Wolfenzon, 2006a, 2006b; Bae, Kang, & Kim, 2002; Bertrand, Mehta, & Mul-
lainathan, 2002; Chang, 2003). Recent studies introduce several forms of tunneling practicesand their consequences
(Cheung, Rau, & Stouraitis, 2006; Jian & Wong, 2010; Jiang, Lee, & Yue,2010). In such cases, minority shareholders
suffer losses from negative firm outcomes. I explore a form of tunneling in which intragroup merger activities aim to
avoid inheritance taxesbut r esultin negative market consequences. Similar tax-saving schemes employed by control-
ling families for their own benefit likely crop up in manyother institutional contexts.
This article is organized as follows: Section 2 introduces the institutional background of inheritance tax reform.
Section 3 describes the data and sample summary statistics. Section 4 discusses the main results. Section 5
concludes.
12An example of avoiding inheritance taxesthrough intragroup mergers in pyramids is detailed in Appendix C.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT