Are CEOs incentivized to shelter good information?

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/fire.12249
AuthorHongrui Feng,Yuecheng Jia
Date01 February 2021
Published date01 February 2021
DOI: 10.1111/fire.12249
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Are CEOs incentivized to shelter good
information?
Hongrui Feng1YuechengJia2
1Finance Department, Sam and Irene Black
School of Business, PennState Behrend, Erie,
Pennsylvania
2Chinese Academyof Finance and
Development,Central University of Finance
and Economics, Beijing, China
Correspondence
HongruiFeng, Sam and Irene Black School of
Business,Penn State Behrend, 4701 College
Erie,PA 16563.
Email:hxf51@psu.edu
Abstract
Prior theoretical studies on the agency problem hold dif-
ferent opinions from the empirical literature on two ques-
tions: (a) Are CEOs incentivized to shelter good informa-
tion? (b) Are CEOs incentivized to evenly shelter good and
bad information? This paper demonstrates that CEOs with
high pay-performanceincentives tend to successfully shelter
good information rather than bad information. Furthermore,
CEOs with high pay-performance incentives shelter good
information by using real earnings management and textual
manipulation but not accrual-based earnings management.
These asymmetric information manipulation behaviors help
to decrease corporate cash flow volatility as well as the jump
and crash risk on the stock market.
KEYWORDS
CEO Delta incentive, good information manipulation, real earnings
management, textual manipulation
JEL CLASSIFICATIONS
G34, J33
1INTRODUCTION
Prior literature documents that investors prefer firms with smooth earnings performance over those with volatile
earnings performance (e.g., Huang, 2009; Rountree, Weston, & Allayannis, 2008). The highly volatile earnings per-
formance is viewed as a signal of high probability of cash flow shortfalls and high costs of externalsources of financing
(e.g.,Minton & Schrand, 1999). Thus, to cater investors’ preference and pursue the maximization of self-interest, CEOs,
especially those with high pay-performance incentives (Delta incentives),tend to withhold information from investors
to smooth earnings performance (e.g., Bergstresser & Philippon, 2006; Benmelech, Kandel, & Veronesi, 2010;Tirole,
2010; Peng & Röell, 2008,2014).
Financial Review. 2021;56:109–132. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/fire ©2020 The Eastern Finance Association 109
110 FENG ANDJIA
Eventhough it is well documented that CEOs with high Delta incentives tend to hoard information from investors, it
is still an unsolved research question whether theychoose to hide good or bad news. CEOs are under asymmetric con-
straintsto hoard good and bad information. On one hand, the delayed revelation of bad news increases CEOs’ exposure
to the litigation risk, which limits the magnitude of bad news withholding (e.g., Skinner,1997; Skinner & Sloan, 2002).
On the other hand, the accounting conservatism principle sets a stricter standard to recognize profits than losses.
Thus, this principle leavesthe space for CEOs to reserve current good news to mitigate the potential bad performance
in the future.
Given the severe litigation risk to hide bad news and the easiness to reserve good news, a natural question is: Do
CEOs with high Delta incentives tend to hide good news rather than bad news? Our paper employs novel measures
on good and bad information-hoarding and finds that CEOs with high Delta incentives prefer to shelter good news
rather than bad news to smooth earnings performance. Further analysis indicates that CEOs with high Delta incen-
tives hide good news via real earnings manipulation and textual manipulation rather than the accrual-based earnings
management.
Our findings hinge on well-defined measures of good and bad news manipulation. Prior literature typically employs
accrual-based measures. However, accrual-based measures havetwo major drawbacks. First, Rountree et al. (2008)
document that investors do not value lower noncash flow–related earnings volatility. In other words, accrual-based
earnings management cannot deviate investors’ valuation on firms. Therefore, to examine the relationship between
information manipulation and investors’ reaction, one can hardly draw reliable conclusions using accrual-based mea-
sures.
The second and more severe drawback is that other than accrual-based earnings management, CEOs have many
moretools at their disposal to manipulate information. Theycan manipulate the information through CEO media expo-
sure, real manipulation, management earnings guidance, and information bundling through 10-X filings1(e.g., Cohen,
Dey,& Lys, 2008; Fudenberg & Tirole, 1995; Graham, Harvey, & Rajgopal, 2005; Hutton, Marcus, & Tehranian,2009;
Kothari,Shu & Wysocki, 2009;Tasker,1998). Thus, accrual-based measures may only partially capture the CEOs’ good
(or bad) information hoarding behaviors.
Therefore, to design a catch-all measure on corporate good and bad news hoarding, we turn to the R2literature
proposed by Roll (1988) and Morck, Yeung, and Yu(2000) among others. Following this line of studies, the R2in our
study is formed from the regression of individual stock returns on market and industry returns. A higher R2of the
market index model indicates a higher comovement with the market and less firm-specific information. Thus, high
R2indicates that less firm-specific information is observed by investors, and more information is hoarded by CEOs.
The R2measure outperforms accrual-based measures from two aspects: (a) it incorporates investors’ reaction to the
information manipulation and (b) it is a catch-all measure of CEOs’ information withholding behaviors.Thus, a positive
relationbetween R2and CEO pay-performance incentives indicates that high equity incentives drive CEOs to withhold
firm-specific information.
Togauge the type of information (either positive or negative) withholding, we employ novelmeasures—the positive
andnegative R2(R2
+andR2
)2.Specifically, a positive R2(R2
+)for a firm/year is the R2associated with the positive weekly
return sample, measuring the informativeness of a firm’s positive marketperformance. By the same token, a negative
R2for a specific firm/yeargauges the informativeness of a firm’s negative market performance.
Our main finding is that CEOs with high pay-performance incentives are associated with a higher R2
+’s but not R2
’s
in all econometric specifications. As a high R2
+is equivalent to the low informativeness of good market performance,
these findings revealthat highly incentivized CEOs shelter only the good news. CEOs’ asymmetric information manip-
ulation is consistent with the combination of two strands of theoretical studies. First, it is consistent with Fudenberg
andTirole(1995)andTirole(2010),who demonstrate that CEOs with high pay-performance incentives are motivated
110-Xreports include 10-K, 10-Q, and so on.
2The positive and negative R2’s are used in asset pricing literature such as Bris, Goetzmann, and Zhu (2007) to capture the informativeness in good and
badconditions.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT