Anonymous Trading in Equities

Date01 April 2021
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12988
AuthorTOM GRIMSTVEDT MELING
Published date01 April 2021
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXVI, NO. 2 APRIL 2021
Anonymous Trading in Equities
TOM GRIMSTVEDT MELING
ABSTRACT
In this paper, I explore a reform at the Oslo Stock Exchange to assess the causal
effect of posttrade trader anonymity on stock liquidity and trading volume. Using
a regression discontinuity approach, I f‌ind that anonymity leads to a reduction in
bid-ask spreads of 40% and an increase in trading volume of more than 50%. The
increase in trading volume is accounted for largely by increased trading activity by
institutional investors, while retail investors do not adjust their trading behavior
in response to anonymity. The results suggest that posttrade anonymity positively
affects standard measures of market quality.
STOCK EXCHANGES CONTINUALLY f‌ine-tune their markets to promote liquid-
ity. A much-used strategy over the last decade has been to alter the degree
to which traders are anonymous. In this paper, I empirically assess the effect
of posttrade anonymity—the concealment of trader identities after completed
trades—on stock liquidity and trading volume. An anonymity reform at the
Oslo Stock Exchange (OSE) allows for causal inference. I f‌ind that posttrade
anonymity increases stock liquidity and trading volume. The increase in trad-
ing volume is accounted for largely by increased trading activity by institu-
tional investors, while retail investors do not adjust their trading behavior in
response to anonymity.
How transparent should trading in equity markets be? Market regulators
have long advocated for more transparency. For example, in 2009, former
Tom Grimstvedt Meling is with the Department of Economics, University of Bergen. This pa-
per has benef‌ited from comments from Signe A. Abrahamsen, Oddmund Berg (discussant), Sjur
D. Flåm, Xavier Giroud, Raffaele Giuliana, Ingar Haaland, TerranceHendershott, Hans K. Hvide,
Hugo Hopenhayn, Jack Light, Katrine V. Løken, Rannveig Huus Meling, Kasper M. Nielsen, Carl
Nilsen, Terrance Odean, Christine Parlour(discussant), K onrad Raff (discussant), Ailsa Röell (dis-
cussant), Øvind Schøyen, Eirik Strømland, Jonas Tungodden, Jialin Yu,and Bernt Arne Ødegaard.
I am also grateful to Bernt Arne Ødegaard for sharing data, and to seminar participants at the
University of Bergen, UC Berkeley Haas, Norwegian School of Economics, EEA, and EWFC for
their valuable comments. I am especially indebted to Stefan Nagel (the editor), two anonymous
referees, and an anonymous associate editor for extensive comments that have greatly helped im-
prove the paper.This work was partially supported by the Research Council of Norway through its
Centres of Excellence Scheme, FAIR project number 262675, and through Finansmarkedsfondet’s
grant number 250215. I have read The Journal of Finance disclosure policy and I have no conf‌licts
of interest to disclose.
Correspondence: Tom Grimstvedt Meling,Department of Economics. University of Bergen, 5007
Bergen, Norway; email: Tom.Meling@uib.no.
DOI: 10.1111/jof‌i.12988
© 2020 the American Finance Association
707
708 The Journal of Finance®
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) chairwoman Mary Schapiro
stated that “Transparency is a cornerstone of the U.S. securities market (...) We
should never underestimate or take for granted the wide spectrum of benef‌its
that come from transparency” (SEC (2009)).1Market participants, in contrast,
caution that too much transparency frustrates their ability to eff‌iciently work
large orders because transparent markets expose their demands and may in-
crease trading costs—thus, harming liquidity.2At least partly in response to
trader demands, leading stock exchanges such as the Nasdaq, London Stock
Exchange, and Deutsche Börse have recently reduced transparency by increas-
ing posttrade anonymity (the Internet Appendix provides an overview of policy
changes).3
Theoretical predictions on the effects of posttrade anonymity on stock liquid-
ity and trading volume come from Kyle (1985)-type models in which informed
traders strategically trade against an uninformed market maker to exploit
their private information. In this setting, Huddart, Hughes, and Levine (2001),
Buffa (2013), and Yang and Zhu (2017) vary whether trader identities become
known after trades.4Yang and Zhu (2017) f‌ind that traders are more willing
to acquire fundamental information when trading is anonymous, resulting in
increased trading volume due to entry by informed traders. With respect to
stock liquidity, Huddart, Hughes, and Levine (2001) and Yang and Zhu (2017)
predict that increased trading on private information in anonymous markets
exacerbates the market maker’s adverse selection problem, which leads to a
reduction in stock liquidity. In contrast, in a setting with risk-averse informed
traders, Buffa (2013) f‌inds that anonymity can increase stock liquidity.
The purpose of this paper is to empirically assess the effect of posttrade
anonymity on stock liquidity and trading volume. To do so, I exploit the fact
that semiannually over the period 2008 to 2010, the 25 most-traded stocks
at the OSE were selected for posttrade anonymous trading, while all others
1Market regulators both in Europe and the United States have recently initiated comprehen-
sive market reforms to increase various aspects of market transparency. For example, the Euro-
pean Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA) recently capped the volumes that can be traded
in the least transparent venues (ESMA (2018)). Similarly, in 2016, the U.S. Financial Industry
Regulatory Authority (FINRA) announced plans to expand its Transparency Initiative by mandat-
ing the public disclosure of block-sized transactions in ATSs, a class of low-transparency trading
venues (FINRA (2016)).
2For example,Øvind Schanke, the head of equity trading at NBIM, the world’s largest sovereign
wealth fund, recently expressed concern about transparent trading to the Wall Street Journal:
“If we sent our orders into the market, we would have to wait days or weeks for our brokers to
execute the trade. Even then, there are risks of information leakage.” See Hope, Bradley, “Upstairs’
Trading Draws More Big Investors,” Wall Street Journal,December 8, 2013.
3The Internet Appendix may be found in the online version of this article.
4A separate theoretical literature studies the impact of pretrade transparency—the extent to
which traders can observe the prices, quantities, or trader identities corresponding to unexecuted
limit orders—on trader behavior and stock liquidity.One strand of the literature f‌inds that trans-
parency increases liquidity by mitigating information asymmetry (e.g., Pagano and Röell (1996)),
while another f‌inds that transparency can reduce liquidity by discouraging informed traders from
placing limit orders (e.g., Rindi (2008), Boulatov and George (2013)). Biais, Glosten, and Spatt
(2005) and Foucault, Pagano, and Röell (2013) survey this literature.
Anonymous Trading in Equities 709
were not. Comparing just-included and just-excluded stocks in a regression
discontinuity design allows for causal estimation. I f‌ind that anonymity signif-
icantly increases stock liquidity and trading volume. For example, the bid-ask
spread, a standard measure of illiquidity and trading costs, is 40% lower for
just-included anonymous stocks than just-excluded stocks, and trading volume
is more than 50% higher. These f‌indings suggest positive effects of posttrade
anonymity on standard measures of market quality.
Improvements in trading volume and stock liquidity may not be due to post-
trade anonymity, but rather to index inclusion effects. Anonymity at the OSE
was determined by membership in the OBX index, a composition of the most-
traded stocks at the OSE. Systematic differences between index and nonindex
stocks, caused (for example) by index benchmarking strategies, can confound
the estimated anonymity effects. To examine whether OBX index stocks are
systematically different from nonindex stocks, I compare index and nonin-
dex stocks in periods before anonymity was introduced. I f‌ind no differences
between marginal index and nonindex stocks in periods without anonymity.
Moreover, index funds typically track the broader Oslo benchmark index, in
which all sampled stocks are included, and not the OBX by itself. For example,
only two index funds track the OBX in the sample period, and their combined
net assets amount to about 5% of the net assets tracking the benchmark index.
Thus, it seems unlikely that index effects are driving the results.
To investigate the mechanisms behind the main empirical results, I f‌irst
note that existing theories posit that anonymity reforms affect market quality
by changing the behavior of informed traders. In the Yang and Zhu (2017)
model, for instance, anonymity increases overall trading volume by inducing
entry by informed traders. To test this mechanism, I use detailed transaction-
level data on the trading of all investors at the OSE. As empirical proxies for
“informed” and “uninformed” investors, I follow Linnainmaa and Saar (2012)
and use institutional and retail investors, respectively. Consistent with the
Yang and Zhu (2017) mechanism, I f‌ind that the observed increase in overall
trading volume under anonymity can be accounted for largely by an increase
in the trading activity of institutional investors, while retail investors do not
adjust their trading behavior in response to anonymity.
Another behavioral response posited by theory relates to how informed
traders execute their orders and underpins informed traders’ attraction to
posttrade anonymous markets. In the Yang and Zhu (2017), Huddart, Hughes,
and Levine (2001), and Buffa (2013) models, anonymity enables informed
traders to split their orders into series of smaller trades to mitigate market
impact and better exploit their private information. This induces positive auto-
correlation in the direction of informed trades, as buys follow buys and sells fol-
low sells. Under transparency, in contrast, such autocorrelated trading strate-
gies may be inferred and exploited by other market participants, and informed
traders must take costly (and thus entry-deterring) actions to conceal their
underlying demands by occasionally buying when the real goal is to sell, and
vice versa. Such “bluff‌ing” reduces the autocorrelation in informed trading.
Brokerage identif‌iers in the transaction-level data allow me to test this

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT