Altruism and Relational Incentives in the Workplace

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12099
AuthorRobert Dur,Jan Tichem
Date01 September 2015
Published date01 September 2015
Altruism and Relational Incentives in the Workplace
ROBERT DUR
Erasmus University Rotterdam, Department of Economics,
and Tinbergen Institute, Rotterdam, The Netherlands
dur@ese.eur.nl
JAN TICHEM
Erasmus University Rotterdam, Department of Economics,
and Tinbergen Institute, Rotterdam, The Netherlands
jan.tichem@acm.nl
This paper studies how altruism between managers and employees affects relational incentive
contracts. To this end, we develop a simple dynamic principal–agent model where both players
may have feelings of altruism or spite toward each other. The contract may contain two types of
incentives for the agent to work hard: a bonus and a threat of dismissal. We find that altruism
undermines the credibility of a threat of dismissal but strengthens the credibility of a bonus.
Among others, these two mechanisms imply that higher altruism sometimes leads to higher
bonuses, whereas lower altruism may increase productivity and players’ utility in equilibrium.
1. Introduction
Incentive contracts for workers often do not rely on objective performance measuresonly.
Indeed, “thinking of any job in which subjective evaluation or supervisor discretion does
not play some role in incentives is difficult” (Gibbs, 2013, p. 411). Subjective performance
evaluation sometimes affects pay. For example, 34% of employees in the industrial sector
in the United Kingdom received some form of merit pay “which depended on a subjec-
tive judgement by a supervisor or manager of the individual’s performance” (quoted
by MacLeod and Malcomson, 1998, from Millward et al., 1992, p. 388).1However, the
use of subjective performance evaluation is not restricted to bonus pay only. Managers
and employees regularly have an understanding that the employment relationship is
only continued if performance is satisfactory, which is often a subjective matter. If the
job is valuable to a worker, such a threat of dismissal also works as an incentive de-
vice (Shapiro and Stiglitz, 1984). A prominent example is Henry Ford’s five-dollar-day
program, which almost doubled wages (Raff and Summers, 1987). Indirect evidence
that many firms use efficiency wages as an incentive device is that bonuses are more
common when the unemployment rate is low, that is, when keeping a job is less valu-
able to a worker (MacLeod and Parent, 2000).
Subjective performance evaluation can overcome some well-known problems re-
lated to the use of objective performance measures, such as multitasking concerns,
Wegratefully acknowledge comments and suggestions by two referees and a co-editor of this journal, Hannes
Mueller, Arjan Non, Canice Prendergast,Anja Sch ¨
ottner, Robin Zoutenbier,Floris Zoutman, and participants
to the 2011 CESifo Area Conference on Behavioural Economics in Munich, the 2011 ZEW/TinbergenInstitute
Workshopon Behavioural Personnel Economics in Mannheim, the 2012 Workshop on the Social Dimension of
Organizations in Budapest, and the 2012 Annual Congress of the European Economic Association in M´
alaga.
1. See MacLeod and Parent (2000) and Gibbs et al. (2004) for similar evidence concerning subjectively
determined bonuses in other sectors.
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume24, Number 3, Fall 2015, 485–500
486 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
measurement costs, and lack of flexibility. When such problems are severe, managers
may revert to “relational contracts” in which employee performance is evaluated sub-
jectively in a holistic way (Gibbons, 1998; Prendergast, 1999). However,a difficulty with
relational contracts is that they cannot be enforced in court, but instead must be self-
enforcing. Promises and threats contained in a relational contract may thereforebe weak
as they are constrained by their credibility. In recent decades, a rich theoretical literature
has developed studying the optimal design and use of relational contracts (see, among
others, Bull, 1987; MacLeod and Malcomson, 1989, 1998; Baker et al., 1994; Levin, 2003).
The present paper contributes to this literature by studying how altruism between
managers and employees affects the optimal design of relational contracts. To this end,
we develop a simple dynamic principal–agent model where both players have some
bargaining power. A moral hazard problem exists because both the agent’s effort and
performance are nonverifiable. For this reason, contracts that condition on effort or
performance are not enforceable in court, and must therefore be self-enforcing. The
contract may contain two types of incentives for the agent to work hard: a promise to
pay a bonus for good performance as in, for example, Baker et al. (1994), and a high
wage combined with a threat of dismissal following bad performance (efficiency wages)
as in Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984). Our key innovation is that we allow both players
to have feelings of altruism and/or spite toward each other. These feelings need not
be symmetric. Our analysis yields several potentially testable hypotheses as well as a
number of management implications.
So far, most studies on relational contracts have abstracted from altruism or spite
between the contracting parties. This is somewhat surprising given the prevalence of re-
lational contracts in the workplace, as described, and the abundance of evidence for the
existence of altruism and spite between managers and employees. Surveys among man-
agers reveal that friendships between managers and employees occur frequently (see
for instance, Berman et al., 2002). Furthermore, Campbell and Kamlani (1997) find that a
large majority of US compensation managers deem good-quality manager–employee re-
lations more important in determining effort than good working conditions, high wages,
and monitoring.2There is also evidence for the occurrence of bad manager–employee
relationships. Moerbeek and Need (2003) report Dutch data showing that in 8% of the
jobs respondents had in their lives, they got along with their manager badly or very
badly. More tentatively, Kahneman et al. (2004) reportdiary evidence from a US sample
of employed women showing that of all regular daily activities, respondents dislike
most to interact with their boss.3
Some of the results from the present analysis can best be compared against the
benchmark of the traditional relational contracts literature, which commonly assumes
selfish preferences. In this respect, our first key result is that higher altruism (meaning
that either the principal, the agent, or both are more altruistic) improves the credibility
of a promise to pay a bonus, ceteris paribus. The reason is twofold. First, higher altruism
makes the relational contract more valuable, which gives the principal stronger incen-
tives to adhere to it. Second, an altruistic principal partly internalizes the benefits of
the bonus to the agent, which reduces the principal’s costs of honoring the contract.
2. In line with this, an extensive literature in organizational psychology has established a strong positive
correlation between the quality of the manager–employee relationship and employee performance (see, e.g.,
Wayne et al., 1997, and Rhoades and Eisenberger, 2002).
3. There is also substantive laboratory evidence indicating that a majority of people are altruistic, even to
strangers, see the review by Andreoni et al. (2008). However, other people areactually spiteful. For instance,
Andreoni and Miller (2002) find that 55% of their sample is altruistic whereas 23% is spiteful.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT