Adaptive capacity to technological change: A microfoundational approach

Published date01 June 2017
AuthorVikas A. Aggarwal,Hart E. Posen,Maciej Workiewicz
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2584
Date01 June 2017
Strategic Management Journal
Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 1212–1231 (2017)
Published online EarlyView 1 November2016 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2584
Received 1 February 2015;Finalrevision received 1 August 2016
ADAPTIVE CAPACITY TO TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE:
A MICROFOUNDATIONAL APPROACH
VIKAS A. AGGARWAL,1*HART E. POSEN,2and MACIEJ WORKIEWICZ3
1INSEAD, Fontainebleau, France
2University of Wisconsin-Madison, Madison, Wisconsin, U.S.A.
3ESSEC Business School, Cergy-Pontoise, France
Research summary: We take a microfoundational approach to understanding the origin of
heterogeneity in rms’ capacity to adapt to technological change. We develop a computational
model of individual-level learning in an organizational setting characterized by interdependence
and ambiguity. The model leads to organizational outcomes with the canonical properties of
routines: constancy,efcacy, and organizational memory.At the same time, the process generating
these outcomes also produces heterogeneity in rms’ adaptive capacity to different types of
technological change. An implication is that exploration policy in the formative period of routine
development can inuence a rm’s capacity to adapt to change in maturity. This points to a host
of strategic trade-offs, not only between performance and adaptive capacity, but also between
adaptive capacities to different forms of change.
Managerial summary: Why are rms differentiallyeffective at adapting to technological change?
We arguethat rms differ in the adaptive capacity of the routines that underlie their capabilities.
These differences arise well beforechange occurs, and result because rms build routines that are
differentially responsive to signals of performance decline associated with technologicalchange.
Thus, early managerial efforts to build superior productive efciency must be complemented
by efforts to build superior adaptive capacity. Our theory suggests that managers can prepare
for technological change by implementing policies, in the formative period of organizational
development, that promote individuals’ explorationof novel actions. However, there aretrade-offs
because preparation aimed at building adaptive capacity to one type of technologicalchange may
limit adaptive capacity to other types of change. Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
INTRODUCTION
The development of the strategy literature has been
strongly inuenced by two key themes: the drivers
of inter-rm performance heterogeneity, and the
factors underlying heterogeneity in the capacity
of rms to adapt to technological change. These
themes have evolved somewhat independently. The
Keywords: microfoundations; routines; adaptive capacity;
technological change; inter-rm heterogeneity
*Correspondence to: Vikas A. Aggarwal, INSEAD, Boulevard
de Constance, 77305 Fontainebleau Cedex, France. E-mail:
vikas.aggarwal@insead.edu
Authors contributed equally and are listed alphabetically.
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
former focuses on endowments of unique resources
and capabilities (e.g., Barney, 1991; Peteraf, 1993;
Winter, 2000), while the latter focuses on fac-
tors such as complementary assets, organizational
interdependencies, and the nature of the change
itself (e.g., Henderson and Clark, 1990; Taylor
and Helfat, 2009; Tripsas, 1997; Tushman and
Anderson, 1986). In this article, we seek to link
these themes theoretically. We propose that the
same process underlying the emergence of routines,
which ultimately serve as building blocks of rm
capabilities, also endows rms with heterogeneity
in the capacity to adapt to technological change.
We suggest, moreover, that a manager’s strategic
choices during the formative period of a routine’s
Adaptive Capacity to Technological Change 1213
development (e.g., via setting the organization’s
exploration policy) may serve as a critical lever,
enabling rms to systematically develop routines
that are differentially adaptable to alternate forms
of technological change.
Organizational routines have become an increas-
ingly central theoretical construct in the strategy
literature because of their close link to rm capa-
bilities (Teece, 1982; Winter, 2000, 2003), and
consequently, the question of whether and how
these routines might change has become impor-
tant (Feldman and Pentland, 2003).1Routines may
reect managerial efforts to purposively coordinate
the actions of individuals— for example, through a
combination of standard operating procedures and
top-down hierarchy (Cyert and March, 1963; March
and Simon, 1958). At the same time, a substan-
tial stream of the literature on routines character-
izes their initial development as stemming from
a bottom-up process of learning (e.g., Cohen and
Bacdayan, 1994; Greve, 2008; Hodgson, 2008;
Hutchins, 1991; Knudsen, 2008; Levitt and March,
1988; Miner, Ciuchta, and Gong, 2008; Nelson and
Winter, 1982) that results in an organization-level
property that can be dened simply as “a repetitive
pattern of interdependent actions, involving mul-
tiple actors” (Feldman and Pentland, 2003: 96).2
These emergent routines then serve as the basis for
“continuity in the behavioral patterns” of organiza-
tions (Nelson and Winter, 1982: 96), and have been
thought to limit adaptation to external change (Han-
nan and Freeman, 1984; Leonard-Barton, 1992).3
1The literature has employed a range of terms that broadly relate
to the term routines. As Cohen, Levinthal, and Warglien (2014)
discuss, a range of “recurring organizational patterns” have been
studied with labels such as routine, practice, standard operating
procedure, etc.They propose using collective performance to
describe such patterns, with the common denominator being that
these all involve “habit-based actions.” This idea is consistent
with what we model here; for simplicity (and because a broader
discussion of terminology is beyond the present scope), we retain
the term routine, recognizing that our use of this term is in the
spirit of this notion of “collective performance.”
2See Becker (2004) for a review of the literature examining the
emergence of routines. Pentland and Feldman (2005) note that,
while standard operating procedures may indeed reect top down
coordination, they may also reect the outcome of a process of
codifying an emergent routine.
3Routines reect one of three mechanisms of organizational coor-
dination (March and Simon, 1958; Thompson, 1967), which
additionally include hierarchical authority and inter-individual
communication. While routines may emerge from bottom-up
individual-learning, the literature has also recognized the impor-
tant role that purposeful managerial action plays on them once
formed (March and Simon, 1958; Teece etal., 1997).
Yet, the literature also recognizes that the mech-
anisms of routine development do not abate after
routine emergence, and routines themselves are able
to adapt in dynamic settings (Feldman and Pent-
land, 2003). Recognizing that routines, as emergent
organizational properties, can and do adapt is a rst
step, but it is not alone sufcient. What matters to
strategy scholars is to identify sources of systematic
heterogeneity. However, the extant literature offers
only a very limited understanding of how systematic
heterogeneity in the capacity of routines to endoge-
nously adapt to technological change emerges and
evolves. Moreover, we have limited insight into the
ways in which managers might guide this process
through explicitly enacted organizational policies.4
To address this gap, we pursue a microfounda-
tional approach (Barney and Felin, 2013; Felin,
Foss, and Ployhart, 2015; Foss and Pedersen, 2014;
Winter, 2013). We propose that the value of doing
so resides not in studying individuals’ behaviors
per se, but rather from identifying how individ-
ual behaviors interact and aggregate to generate
macro-level phenomena. Our approach is anchored
in individual-level learning and the formation of
“habit” (Winter, 2013). To the degree that routines
can be conceptualized as “structures of interlocking
individual habits” (Hodgson, 2008: 25), the evolv-
ing beliefs of individuals are central not only to the
emergence of routines (Becker, 2004; Greve, 2008;
Knudsen, 2008; Levitt and March, 1988; Miner
et al., 2008), but also to their endogenous evolution
and adaptation over time (Becker et al., 2005).
We computationally model a process that could
lead to the emergence of routines in organizations.
We build on the bandit model of individual learn-
ing under uncertainty (e.g., March, 1996; Posen
and Levinthal, 2012), extending this to an orga-
nizational environment in which one individual’s
actions impact the outcomes of the others in the
organization (Levinthal and March, 1993; Thomp-
son, 1967). The individual-level learning process is
one in which individuals observe organization-level
outcomes, and then update beliefs based on these
outcomes. Individuals thus act in the context of sub-
stantial ambiguity (March and Olsen, 1975). As a
baseline result, our model of individual-level learn-
ing in an ambiguous organizational environment
produces outcomes with the canonical properties
of routines: constancy, efcacy, and organizational
4See Foss et al. (2012) for a recent discussion that highlights these
issues.
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J.,38: 1212–1231 (2017)
DOI: 10.1002/smj

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT