Why is free education so popular? A political economy explanation

AuthorJuan A. Correa,Yijia Lu,Mauricio Villena,Francisco Parro
Date01 August 2020
Published date01 August 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12396
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:973991. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet © 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
973
Received: 25 June 2018
|
Revised: 4 June 2019
|
Accepted: 1 August 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12396
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Why is free education so popular? A political
economy explanation
Juan A. Correa
1
|
Yijia Lu
2
|
Francisco Parro
3
|
Mauricio Villena
3
1
Facultad de Economia y Negocios,
Universidad Andres Bello, Santiago,
Chile
2
School of Law, New York University,
New York, New York
3
School of Business, Universidad Adolfo
Ibáñez, Santiago, Chile
Correspondence
Francisco Parro, School of Business,
Universidad Adolfo Ibáñez, 7941169,
Santiago, Chile.
Email: fjparrog@gmail.com
Abstract
This paper analyzes the political support for different
funding regimes of education in a oneperson, onevote
democracy. We focus the analysis on four systems that
have had a preponderant presence in the political debate
on education: a private system, a public system that
delivers the same resources to each student (universal
free education), a public system that intends to equalize
results, and a public system that aims to maximize the
output of the economy. We show that a system of
universal free education is the Condorcet winner. The
level of income inequality and the degree to which
income distribution is skewed to the right are key factors
behind this conclusion. We also show that the voting
outcome of public versus private funding for education
depends crucially on the type of public funding under
consideration.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Universal free education has become popular in several regions of the world. Western
democracies have it at different stages of the educational ladder. European countries, such as
France, provide free tuition to European students, and Germany offers free tuition even to
international students. Argentina, the Czech Republic, and Greece supply free education at all
educational levels. Most of the United States primary and secondary students attend public
schools, which provide free education, funded by a mix of federal, regional, and local
resources.
1
In other countries, such as Chile, South Africa, and the United Kingdom, where
1
An extensive crosscountry analysis of educations tuition fee schemes can be found in Bentaouet Kattan (2006).
higher education is not free, social movements have pressured the authorities to implement a
scheme of universal free education for higher education.
2
In this paper, we give a political
economy explanation for the popularity of free education.
A system of universal free education allocates public funds equally across students. This
system, however, is not completely consistent with the main implications of a strand of the
literature that emphasizes, first, the importance of economic growth to improve living standards
and, second, human capital investments as the engine to promote growth (Benhabib & Spiegel,
1994; Hanushek & Kimko, 2000; among others). This branch of the literature points to a system
in which public resources for education should be allocated to students with higher skills (so as
to maximize aggregate output), relying on alternative instruments for redistribution. Universal
free education also implies that public funds are allocated regardless of the students family
income. However, studies such as Samoff (1996) and Larkin and Staton (2001) highlight the
importance of equity in the allocation of public resources spent on education. This implies that
disadvantaged students should be supported with more resources, which would allow
equalizing human capital across students. Hence, universal free education does not point in
the direction suggested by these two strands of the literature.
A third strand of the literature suggests that different public funding systems should be
implemented at different stages of the educational system. Empirical studies document low
returns to interventions targeting disadvantaged adolescents, but high economic returns for
remedial investments targeting young disadvantaged children (Cunha & Heckman, 2007;
Cunha, James, Lochner, & Masterov, 2006; Heckman, 2008; Heckman & Masterov, 2007). This
evidence implies an equityefficiency tradeoff for late child investments but not for early
investments (Cunha & Heckman, 2007). Thus, public resources for education should focus on
lowincome students at earlier stages. However, at later stages, when human capital inequalities
are difficult to undo, public resources should be shifted toward highhuman capital students so
as to maximize output, relying on an alternative instrument for socially desirable redistribution.
The popularity of free education at different stages of education is not completely aligned with
the implications derived from this third strand of the literature.
Then, why is universal free education so popular in the world? This paper gives a political
economy explanation for this popularity. We model a static economy populated by a continuum
of heterogeneous agents or parents, and each of them has one child and must vote for the
funding regime that will finance the education of the child. Parents are heterogeneous in terms
of human capital, which equals the family income. The parentshuman capital is exogenously
given and distributed according to a lognormal distribution function, as in Glomm and
Ravikumar (1992) and Becker (1993). We study the Condorcet winner among four funding
regimes that frequently appear in the political debate: a private system, a public system that
delivers the same resources to all students, a public system that intends to equalize results, and
a public system that aims to maximize the output of the economy.
Our analysis shows that a public system that universally invests the same resources in each
student is the Condorcet winner in a oneperson, onevote democracy. The intuition behind our
2
In Chile, the Confederation of Chilean Student Federations (CONFECH), a national body made up of students at Chilean universities, led a series of student
protests across the country in 2011. The student movement demanded, among other things, an increase in state support for public universities and free public
education. In South Africa, the Fees Must Fallmovement emerged in 2015 after the government announced an increase in mandatory fees at the universities.
Students were placated after the proposal for the increase was dropped. The 2010 United Kingdom student protests were a series of demonstrations held in
opposition to the planned increase of the cap on tuition fees by the ConservativeLiberal Democrat coalition government. The biggest demonstration occurred
in November 2010, officially known under the phrase of Fund Our Future: Stop Education Cuts,where thousands of students marched through central
London demanding free education.
974
|
CORREA ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT