Why Hybrid Bicameralism Is Not Right for Sortition*

DOI10.1177/0032329218789893
Published date01 September 2018
Date01 September 2018
AuthorTerrill Bouricius
Subject MatterSpecial Issue Articles
https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329218789893
Politics & Society
2018, Vol. 46(3) 435 –451
© The Author(s) 2018
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0032329218789893
journals.sagepub.com/home/pas
Special Issue Article
Why Hybrid Bicameralism Is
Not Right for Sortition*
Terrill Bouricius
Former member, Vermont House of Representatives
Abstract
Structural problems are examined with pairing two chambers, one selected by
election and the other by sortition, into a traditional bicameral system. It is argued
that an all-purpose legislative chamber modeled on existing elected chambers is a
mismatch for sortition and that purported benefits of maintaining partisan elections
alongside sortition are illusory. Alleged benefits of a hybrid bicameral system are
shown to be outweighed by a variety of harmful effects. Furthermore, even if those
harms are not substantiated, the continued existence of an elected chamber will likely
result in the delimitation of the sortition chamber. Combining many different sorts
of minipublics with different characteristics and functions is preferable, and a possible
multibody sortition legislative system is presented. Finally, an alternative way forward
for sortition is proposed by peeling away individual topic areas from elected bodies
and transferring them to sortition bodies.
Keywords
bicameral legislature, corruption, deliberation, democracy, elections, minipublics,
random selection, representation, sortition
Corresponding Author:
Terrill Bouricius, 56 Booth Street, Burlington, VT 05401, USA.
Email: terrybour@gmail.com
*This special issue of Politics & Society titled “Legislature by Lot: Transformative Designs for Deliberative
Governance” features a preface, an introductory anchor essay and postscript, and six articles that
were presented as part of a workshop held at the University of Wisconsin–Madison, September 2017,
organized by John Gastil and Erik Olin Wright.
789893PASXXX10.1177/0032329218789893Politics & SocietyBouricius
research-article2018
436 Politics & Society 46(3)
Proposals for incorporating sortition into the lawmaking process frequently envision a
hybrid bicameral legislature with the members of one of the chambers selected by lot.1
This could be a transitional model on the path to a fully sortition-based legislature—
sort of a trial run to see whether such a body can behave in a competent manner. But
for many theorists it is the final goal. Gastil and Wright argue that despite a host of
problems with election-based representation, important beneficial aspects of an elected
chamber would be lost in an all-sortition system. I will argue that the purported bene-
fits of maintaining elections are illusory. Also, the all-purpose legislative chamber
design is a mismatch for sortition; it would sabotage sortition’s hoped for benefits and
delegitimize a sortition chamber. I will conclude by arguing that there are better ways
to evolve into a virtually all-sortition lawmaking system.
Purported Benefits of Maintaining an Elected Chamber
In this section, I will examine several commonly asserted benefits of maintaining an
elected chamber alongside a sortition chamber. Citizens would be loath to forfeit an
elected chamber for fear of losing at least four presumed benefits: the societal benefits
of parties; the utility of having elected officials as authorized negotiators; the political
leadership cultivated by electoral politics; and the political expertise provided by
elected officials. In turn, I will cast doubt on the existence, or importance, of each.
Benefits of Parties
Without elections it is suggested that parties would atrophy, yet parties ideally play an
important role in formulating political programs, educating the public about policy
alternatives, and mobilizing citizens. Others argue that US parties “have become little
more than political labels behind which well-financed candidates organize their elec-
toral bids.”2
Parties would inevitably change in an all-sortition system, but they would not nec-
essarily atrophy. Active political parties have organized across the globe under non-
electoral regimes, even when outlawed. Rather than contending in elections, parties
would aim to influence the general public, who would form the minipublics. And, of
course, political parties are not the only avenue for important social mobilization, with
Black Lives Matter, Occupy Wall Street, or the pro-life movements in the United
States being examples. With parties stripped of their unique electoral significance,
such popular mobilizations might be more common and effective under a sortition
system.
But let us focus on the effects of eliminating the competitive electoral function of
political parties in an all-sortition democracy. Anthoula Malkopoulou argues that vot-
ing in elections “offers a real and continuous relationship between government and
citizens that, aided by the excitement of competition, produces a higher incentive to
stay informed and form an opinion about general political issues.”3 She speculates that
“sortition does away with the momentum of discursive interaction and contestation,
which the experience of election provides.”4

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT