When Voters Pull the Trigger: Can Direct Democracy Restrain Legislative Excesses?

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12115
AuthorVladimir Kogan
Published date01 May 2016
Date01 May 2016
VLADIMIR KOGAN
The Ohio State University
When Voters Pull the Trigger:
Can Direct Democracy Restrain
Legislative Excesses?
Direct democracy is sometimes described as a “gun behind the door,” but how
do legislators react when voters pull the trigger? Leveraging the high-profile referendum
defeat of a controversial law passed by the Ohio legislature, I examine how legislators
respond to voter disaffection. Using interest groups to “bridge” votes before and after
the election, I show that the measure’s defeat induced moderation on the part of the
Republican legislative majority, while leaving the behavior of opposition Democrats
largely unchanged. The results suggest that direct democracy has the potential to restrain
legislative excesses and alleviate polarization in state legislatures.
“That’s the big problem here. You’re here to represent your people, but you don’t
know what they want. The onlyway to really know is to take a referendum.”
Anonymous congressman, quotedin Kingdon (1973, 32)
Growing evidence suggests that partisan polarization, a national
phenomenon since the 1970s (McCarty, Poole, and Rosenthal 2006), is
accelerating in state legislatures as well (Shor and McCarty 2011). Just
as ideological divisions among elites appear to produce “leapfrog” repre-
sentation in Congress (Bafumi and Herron 2010)—with electoral
turnover resulting in policy change but little improvement in congruence
between policy and constituent preferences—increasing partisanship
threatens to undermine democratic responsiveness in the American
states. Lax and Phillips, for example, document a sizeable representa-
tional gap in state government and show that this democratic def‌icit is
“connected to the overresponsiveness to voter ideology and the distorting
inf‌luence of party control” (2011, 149). If elections that replace incum-
bent legislators with their opponents from the opposite party prove
ineffective in remedying the problem of legislative extremism, and if
institutional reforms such as independent redistricting commissions and
open primaries offer little hope (Kogan and McGhee 2012; McCarty,
LEGISLATIVE STUDIES QUARTERLY, 41, 2, May 2016 297
DOI: 10.1111/lsq.12115
V
C2016 Washington University in St. Louis
Poole, and Rosenthal 2009; McGhee 2012), what can be done to
improverepresentationinaneraofsharppartisandiscord?
This study documents how direct democracy may, under certain
circumstances, provide voters with a mechanism to restrain legislative
excesses. Since its adoption by some states in the late nineteenth and
early twentieth centuries, direct democracy has been viewed by many
reformers and democratic theorists as an essential mechanism for
strengthening the link between citizens and their government. In addition
to empowering voters to shape policy at the ballot box, these institutions
may also serve as an effective “gun behind the door” that motivates bet-
ter representation among their elected agents (e.g., Gerber 1996, 1999).
Aside from its effects on policy through these channels, however, I argue
that direct democracy can also serve an important informational role by
signaling to elected off‌icials the preferences of their constituents.
In an increasingly polarized world, when voters must choose
between two distant and unsatisfying options in candidate contests
(Fiorina, Abrams, and Pope 2005), electoral victors may struggle to dis-
cern the voters’ true intent or preferred policy agenda once in off‌ice.
Under such circumstances, it becomes tempting for legislators to misread
the electoral tea leaves and conclude that voters have given them a
“mandate” where none in fact exists (Grossback, Peterson, and Stimson
2007; Peterson et al. 2003) and act on this belief to implement an ideo-
logical policy agenda. When voters are able to respond to such excesses
by “pulling the trigger,” legislators can observe the outcomes of direct
democracy elections, update their beliefs about the distribution of voter
preferences, and accordingly moderate their behavior in off‌ice.
Taking advantage of Ohio’s high-prof‌ile referendum defeat in
2011, I provide evidence that direct democracy can indeed serve as a
moderating check on legislative extremism. After gaining control of
both legislative chambers and the governor’s off‌ice in a Tea Party-fueled
electoral wave during the 2010 midterm elections, Ohio’s new Republi-
can majority acted quickly to put in place conservative public policies.
Less than a year later, however, voters had the opportunity to show their
widespread disaffection with the direction pursued by Republican law-
makers, rejecting a controversial and unpopular overhaul of public
sector collective bargaining laws in November 2011. Republican leaders
acknowledged their defeat: on Election Night, the governor suggested
that the voters had signalled that his agenda was “too much too soon”; a
top legislative leader admitted that “the voters have spoken, [and] we
have heard them.” Using interest groups to “bridge” roll-call votes
immediately before and after the election, I show that the measure’s
defeat induced moderation on the part of the Republican legislative
298 Vladimir Kogan

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT