When to Lean against the Wind

AuthorPAUL WACHTEL,MORITZ SCHULARICK,BJÖRN RICHTER
Published date01 February 2021
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jmcb.12701
Date01 February 2021
DOI: 10.1111/jmcb.12701
BJÖRN RICHTER
MORITZ SCHULARICK
PAUL WACHTEL
When to Lean against the Wind
In this paper, we show that policymakerscan distinguish between good and
bad credit booms with high accuracy and they can do so in real time. Ev-
idence from 17 countries over nearly 150 years of modern nancial his-
tory shows that credit booms that are accompanied by house price booms
and a rising loan-to-deposit ratio are much more likely to end in a systemic
banking crisis than other credit booms. We evaluatethe predictive accuracy
for different classication models and show that characteristics observed in
real time contain valuable information for sorting the data into good and
bad booms.
JEL codes: E32, E44, G01, G21
Keywords: banking crises, crisis prediction, credit booms,
macroprudential policy
P    , credit booms, can have
diverse outcomes. First, there is a large literature that relates credit growth with
improved economic fundamentals and argues that such nancial deepening episodes
are economically benecial. Second, some credit booms end badly; they result in
nancial crises with severe output losses. This means that policymakers eager to
avoid the debilitating effects of banking crises have to walk a ne line between the
two pitfalls of failing to intervene to stop a bad boom and being too activist and
choking off economic growth. Measures to dampen credit booms may reduce the
This work is part of a larger project kindly supported by a research grant from the Bundesministerium
für Bildung und Forschung (BMBF). We are indebted to a large number of researchers who helped with
data on individual countries. Special thanks to the participants at the American Economic Association
meetings in Philadelphia January 2018, the Bank of Finland seminar in June 2018, the 23rd Dubrovnik
Economic Conference in June 2017, the Halle Workshop on Macroeconomics in May 2017, and the LSE
SRC Conference on Financial Crises in April 2018. We are grateful to John Ducca, Evan Kraft, Olivier
Jeanne, Philip Jung, and Alan M. Taylor for helpful comments. All errors are our own.
B R is an Assistant Professor at the Department of Economics and Business, Universitat
Pompeu Fabra and an Afliated Professor at Barcelona GSE (E-mail: bjorn.richter@upf.edu). M
S is a Professor of Economics at the Department of Economics, University of Bonn and CEPR
(E-mail: schularick@uni-bonn.de). P W is a Professorof Economics at Stern School of Busi-
ness, New YorkUniversity (E-mail: pwachtel@stern.nyu.edu).
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 53, No. 1 (February 2021)
© 2020 The Ohio State University
6:MONEY,CREDIT AND BANKING
risk of a banking crisis, but also reduce growth with uncertain costs for the economy
(Svensson 2017, Adrian and Liang 2018).
Policymakers face a problem whenever they observe a period of rapid credit
growth. That is, can they determine whether the boom underway will lead to a crisis?
In this paper, we identify credit boom episodes and demonstrate that policymakers
can distinguish good booms from bad ones and that they can do so with data available
in real time. We show that there are clear markers that policymakers can use to tell
apart good from bad credit booms with considerable accuracy. Financial variables
such as a deteriorating liquidity position (measured by the loan-to-deposit ratio) and
a house price boom are powerful classiers to sort credit boom observations into
malign and benign. Among the set of real economic variables, only changes in the
current-account-to-GDP balance turn out to be a helpful classier.
We arriveat this conclusion by studying long-run data for 17 advanced economies
from 1870 to 2016. We rely on economic and nancial data from the Macrohistory
Database (Jordà, Schularick, and Taylor 2016), as well as the systemic banking
crisis chronology contained therein, which is based on a large number of historical
sources as well as the crisis data set compiled by Laeven and Valencia (2018). We
use the new Hamilton (2018) lter to detrend the data and dene credit booms as
periods when the log of real private credit per capita exceeds its predicted value by
a country-specic threshold. We identify 113 credit boom episodes and 90 systemic
banking crises in our sample of advanced economies over the past 150 years.
Only a few papers have examined credit booms and their outcomes (Mendoza and
Terrones 2014, Dell’Ariccia et al. 2016, Gorton and Ordoñez 2020). Yet since the
time series examined are short and the country experiences are very heterogeneous,
these studies often face challenges to distinguish good booms from bad booms based
on observable characteristics.1Our long-run historical data have the advantage that
we can analyze within-country experiences as most of the sample countries have
experienced both good and bad credit booms at some point in their history.2
The growth of credit has been of interest to economic historians, development
economists, and students of macronance for at least 30 years. Our paper connects
two important and seemingly contradictory strands in the literature (Wachtel 2018).
On the one hand, there is a literature on the nance-growth nexus that associates
credit deepening and the quality of nancial intermediation with economic growth
(King and Levine 1993, Rancière, Tornell, and Westermann 2008). There is a volu-
minous literature that uses post-World War II panel data that have been surveyed by
Levine (2005). The evidence indicates that countries with deeper nancial markets,
a higher credit to GDP ratio, or larger stock market capitalization, experience more
rapid growth. Evidence for the positive effects of nancial booms is also examined
by Rousseau and Wachtel (2017) who use historical data for the period 1870–1929
1. Dell’Ariccia et al. (2016) conclude that most indicators that have been suggested in the literature
lose signicance once one conditions for the existence of a credit boom.
2. However, this comes at the cost of focusing on a sample of developed, largely industrial,
countries only.
BJÖRN RICHTER, MORITZ SCHULARICK, AND PAULWACHTEL :7
and afrm the positive growth effects of nancial deepening. However, Rousseau
and Wachtel (2009) indicate that positive growth effects of nancial deepening have
weakened since the mid-1980s which coincides with an increase in the incidence of
nancial crises.
On the other hand, there is an equally large literature that associates credit booms
with banking crises. Despite the potential benets of nancial deepening, many
credit booms end in often debilitating banking crises with severe effects on the real
economy (Schularick and Taylor 2012, Jordà, Schularick, and Taylor 2013, Mian and
Su 2016). More recently, Mian, Su, and Verner (2017) have shown that household
credit booms predict bad growth outcomes in more recent cross-country samples. In
short, while some credit booms are a precursor to banking distress and crisis, other
credit booms might represent nancial deepening or be the reaction to a positive
productivity shock.
There is also a large literature on crisis prediction that tries to identify crisis indica-
tors and early warning signals (Borio and Drehmann 2009, Detken et al. 2014, Adrian,
Covitz, and Liang 2015, Aldasoro, Borio, and Drehmann 2018, Kiley 2018). Since
the great nancial crisis there has been increased emphasis on macroprudential risks
and policy and indicators based on detailed nancial sector data that are now available
(Cerutti, Claessens, and Laeven 2017). Crisis prediction is a daunting task because at
any point in time, the probability of a nancial crisis occurring is quite small and un-
likely to attract the attention of policymakers.3The approach that we take here is very
different than the crisis prediction literature. It is motivated by the idea that once a
policymaker observes that a credit boom is underway and the economy is in the credit-
boom state, the possibility of crisis warrants attention. For this reason, we depart from
the crisis prediction literature and use the credit boom as our unit of observation. Our
interest in this paper is not to predict crises but instead to provide information that
would help policymakers determine whether an observed credit boom is likely to end
badly. To the best of our knowledge, ours is the rst paper to show that it is possi-
ble to identify markers that distinguish bad booms from good booms in real time, an
important prerequisite for the decision whether to intervene during a credit boom.
The challenge faced by the policymaker is whether a country in a credit boom can
use available information to determine whether prudential or other policies should be
used to deal with the risks of a credit boom turning into a crisis (Cerutti, Claessens,
and Laeven 2017, Adrian and Liang 2018). The prevailing opinion prior to the recent
global nancial crisis was that monetary policymakers should focus on growthand in-
ation and rely on micronancial regulation to maintain nancial stability (Bernanke
and Gertler 1999). Federal Reserve Board Chairman Alan Greenspan, commenting
on the possibility of a bubble bursting famously said that “the job of economic policy
makers [is] to mitigate the fallout when it occurs” (Greenspan 1999). Yet even before
the global nancial crisis, some economists, notably at the Bank for International Set-
tlements, suggested that systemic risks warranted the introduction of macroprudential
3. Svensson (2017) argues that the relationship between credit growth and crisis incidence is based
on so many complex interactions that it is impossible to identify a stable and consistent crisis predictor.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT