When Law Enforcement Pays: Costs and Benefits for Elected Versus Appointed Administrators Engaged in Asset Forfeiture

Published date01 April 2020
Date01 April 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/0275074019891993
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/0275074019891993
American Review of Public Administration
2020, Vol. 50(3) 297 –314
© The Author(s) 2019
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0275074019891993
journals.sagepub.com/home/arp
Article
Introduction
Under forfeiture laws, law enforcement organizations seize
billions of dollars a year from U.S. citizens. Some of this
revenue is connected to a criminal conviction, but a majority
accrues from civil forfeiture proceedings,1 which do not
require a conviction or even charges be filed. The issue of
civil asset forfeiture has gained salience of late because of
concerns about the tension that such activities create between
law enforcement and citizens and the consequences when
those tensions boil over in places like Ferguson, MO. While
most of the media attention has focused on civil asset forfei-
ture (see, for example, Sallah et al., 2014; Stillman, 2013), a
recent supreme court case (Timbs v. Indiana) has also refo-
cused public attention on the possibility that assets forfeited
after criminal convictions may violate constitutional prohibi-
tions against the levying of excessive fines.
Not surprisingly, given its controversial nature, asset for-
feiture has been a subject of significant interest among legal
and criminal justice scholars, but we argue that the practice
raises important questions about equity and fairness in the
administration of public programs and laws and should be of
interest to scholars of public administration as well. In this
article, we are particularly interested in the degree to which
asset forfeiture offers opportunities to refine theory about dif-
ferences between elected and appointed officials who deliver
comparable public services. We make this assertion because
work to date has not sufficiently explored seizures by more
than 3,000 sheriff’s departments across the country. Based
on jurisdictional data on total forfeiture revenue, sheriffs
account for one third of forfeiture dollars and, thus, have a
meaningful impact on the effect of seizure activity on citizens.2
Furthermore, the vast majority of sheriffs are elected, rather
than appointed like municipal police chiefs, which means
that work to date has neglected whether the electoral moti-
vations of the former lead to differences in the behavior of
these two sets of public administrators. Finally, the presence
891993ARPXXX10.1177/0275074019891993The American Review of Public AdministrationMughan et al.
research-article2019
1Indiana University Bloomington, USA
Corresponding Author:
Sean Nicholson-Crotty, O’Neill School of Public and Environmental
Affairs, Indiana University Bloomington, 1315 E. 10th St. #410E,
Bloomington, IN 47405, USA.
Email: seanicho@indiana.edu
When Law Enforcement Pays: Costs and
Benefits for Elected Versus Appointed
Administrators Engaged in Asset Forfeiture
Siân Mughan1, Danyao Li1, and Sean Nicholson-Crotty1
Abstract
The billions of dollars in assets seized by law enforcement each year represent a crucial source of revenue for these
organizations, but also raise important constitutional questions and can create significant tensions within the jurisdictions
they administer. Research on asset forfeiture to date has focused heavily on municipal police, largely neglecting forfeiture
activities by sheriffs. Thus, it has missed an important opportunity to build theory about the differences between appointed
and elected administrators and neglected an important source of institutional variation that may help to explain this
particular administrative activity. To develop expectations about the relative levels of asset forfeiture and the response to
intergovernmental incentives related to forfeiture, we draw on and extend scholarship comparing the behavior of elected
versus appointed administrators in other settings. We test those expectations in analyses of more than 1,200 sheriff’s offices
and over 2,200 municipal police departments between 1993 and 2007. Results suggest that sheriffs receive less forfeiture
revenue than municipal police and are less responsive to state-level policies that change the financial rewards of asset
forfeiture for agencies. These results hold whether we examine forfeitures made through the federal Equitable Sharing
Program, where civil and criminal forfeiture cases can be distinguished, or jurisdictional level data on forfeiture, where
civil and criminal forfeitures are combined. We conclude with a discussion of implications for both the research on asset
forfeiture and on elected versus appointed public administrators more generally.
Keywords
asset forfeiture, revenue-orientated policing, method of selection, electoral motivation
298 American Review of Public Administration 50(3)
of state and federal policies meant to increase asset forfei-
ture among local agencies, mean that this is a great place to
examine hitherto unexplored questions about the impact of
intergovernmental incentives on elected versus appointed
administrators.
To develop expectations about the relative levels of asset
forfeiture, as well as the response to intergovernmental
incentives, we draw on the literature comparing elected ver-
sus appointed administrators in other settings. This work
suggests that the relative need to satisfy voters creates differ-
ences in the behaviors of these actors (see, for example,
Besley & Coate, 2003). In this context, theory suggests that
sheriffs face potential electoral costs from seizing voter
property that they must weigh against the monetary benefits,
whereas municipal police do not face such costs, at least not
directly. Because of this calculation, we expect that sheriffs
receive less forfeiture revenue than municipal police, all else
being equal. We also extend existing work by considering
how the electoral motivation affects the impact of intergov-
ernmental incentives on the behavior of administrators.
Specifically, we develop the expectation that the electoral
costs for sheriffs should offset, and therefore reduce, the
effect of state-level policies that increase the monetary ben-
efit of forfeiture for local law enforcement.
We test these expectations in an analysis of 1,247 sheriff
offices and 2,278 municipal police departments between
1993 and 2007. We examine civil forfeiture and criminal for-
feiture revenue from the federal Equitable Sharing Program,
as well as total forfeiture revenue reported by the agencies.
Results suggest that sheriffs consistently report significantly
less revenue from asset forfeiture than do police depart-
ments. They also suggest that sheriffs are less responsive to
state policies that allow local law enforcement agencies to
keep a larger portion of seized revenue. We conclude with a
discussion of the implications of these results for our under-
standing of civil asset forfeiture and the behavior of elected
versus appointed administrators more generally.
Asset Forfeiture
Civil asset forfeiture is a two-step process. First, law enforce-
ment seizes private property believed to be connected to
criminal activity. Afterward, the seized assets are forfeited
(i.e., kept) by the government, with the proceeds typically
reverting to the seizing agency. Modern policies date back to
The Comprehensive Drug Abuse Prevention and Control Act
of 1970 which included a civil forfeiture provision, allowing
law enforcement to seize and forfeit “. . . drugs, drug manu-
facturing and storage equipment, and conveyances used to
transport drugs” (Blumenson & Nilsen, 1998, p. 44).3 The
intent was twofold, to mitigate the financial gains from par-
ticipating in the drug trade and to incentivize law enforce-
ment to do more anti-drug policing by allowing the agency to
retain a portion, if not the entirety, of the proceeds from
forfeited property. Over time, the list of seizable assets has
expanded to include almost any type of property including,
but not limited to, cash and real property, and every state has
adopted civil asset forfeiture laws of their own.
Civil asset forfeiture has proven to be highly controver-
sial. For starters, it is a civil and not criminal proceeding,
meaning a criminal conviction (or even criminal charges) are
not required; property may be seized and forfeited on suspi-
cion of connection to criminal activity.4 Scholarship suggests
that the majority of civil forfeitures occur without a charge,
or even an arrest (see, for example, Burnett, 2008; Sallah
et al., 2014). Moreover, because it is a civil case, the property
owner is entitled to fewer legal protections, making it easier
for the government to ultimately forfeit the seized property.5
Also, contentious are the financial incentives created by
allowing law enforcement agencies access to seizure reve-
nues. Given the important source of revenue that forfeitures
represent for many jurisdictions, a number of authors have
argued that they create questionable incentives for police
behavior and distract law enforcement from their primary
mandate of protecting public safety (Benson et al., 1995;
Blumenson & Nilsen, 1998).6 Actual empirical evidence on
whether police departments strategically focus on certain
types of arrests to maximize forfeiture revenue is mixed,
although studies of individual jurisdictions have suggested a
relationship between police behavior and forfeiture (see, for
example, D’Alessio et al., 2015; Kelly & Kole, 2016; Miller
& Selva, 1994). Regardless of their effect on incentives,
researchers and law enforcement officials both emphasize the
importance of forfeiture revenue (Cassella, 1997, 2004; Coe
& Wiesel, 2001; Williams, 2002), with one author finding that
40% of police executives reported forfeiture proceeds as
essential to their operational budgets (Worrall, 2001).
The extent to which state and local agencies are able to
profit off of civil asset forfeiture is governed by state law;
only seven states and the District of Columbia prohibit law
enforcement agencies from profiting at all from seizures,
whereas 25 states allow law enforcement to keep 100% of
forfeited revenue. However, the authority of state laws is
compromised by the federal Equitable Sharing Program, cre-
ated by the 1984 Comprehensive Crime Control Act. Under
the Equitable Sharing Program, state and local agencies seize
property under federal law, the federal government then pro-
cesses the seized assets, and shares the proceeds with the
state or local law enforcement agency once the asset is for-
feited (U.S. Department of Justice, 2009).7
Somewhat surprisingly, researchers have failed to demon-
strate a relationship between the generosity of state incentives
and the amount of revenue seized (Worrall & Kovandzic,
2008). Worrall and Kovandzik (2008) suggest, however, that
the null relationship between state monetary incentives and
seizure behavior is due to the fact that departments in restric-
tive states circumvent state laws through greater participation
in the Equitable Sharing Program. In other words, agencies in
states with restrictive laws regarding civil forfeiture are able
to circumvent those laws by allowing the federal government

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT