Welfare‐increasing third‐degree price discrimination

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12128
Published date01 May 2016
AuthorSimon Cowan
Date01 May 2016
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.47, No. 2, Summer 2016
pp. 326–340
Welfare-increasing third-degree price
discrimination
Simon Cowan
When demand functions in different markets are derived from distributions of reservation prices
that differ only in their means, conditions exist such that third-degree price discrimination leads
to greater total output and greater total welfare. Welfare is higher with discrimination than with
a uniform price when demand functions are derived from logistic distributions with different
means. Welfare and consumer surplus are higher with discrimination for demands derived from
a distribution related to the Pareto. In general, whether discrimination increases total output
depends on demand being more convex in markets in which prices fall with discrimination than
in those in which prices rise.
1. Introduction
Under what conditions does third-degree price discrimination lead to greater social welfare
than uniform (nondiscriminatory) pricing? This is a long-standing question in economics that
has only been answered partially. This article provides broader answers. In particular, it shows
that social welfare is raised if demand functions are derived from logistic distributions that differ
only in their means, and that total output is higher with discrimination for many similar demand
functions with differing means.
A monopolist using third-degree price discrimination divides customers into separate mar-
kets on the basis of observable characteristics and sets prices that vary across the markets.
Alternatively, the firm may be unable to discriminate, because of regulation or arbitrage, and
thus must set a common price across markets. Pigou (1920) showed that if demand functions are
linear and all markets are served with positive quantities at the uniform price, then a move to
discriminatory prices keeps total output constant. In this case, discrimination reduces social wel-
fare (the sum of consumer surplus and profits), because the welfare-maximizing way to allocate
output across markets requires equating marginal utilities, which only a common price ensures.
If welfare is to rise with discrimination, there must be an increase in output sufficient to offset
the misallocation effect. Much of the literature since Pigou has been somewhat negative about
the welfare effects of third-degree price discrimination. Aguirre, Cowan, and Vickers (2010)
University of Oxford; simon.cowan@economics.ox.ac.uk.
I am grateful to two referees, Ben Hermalin, I˜
naki Aguirre, Achim Czerny, Peter Neary, Markus Reisinger, Marius
Schwartz, Glen Weyl,and participants at the 2013 SAET conference in Paris and of seminars at UC Dublin and WHU in
Vallendarin 2014 for helpful comments and suggestions.
326 C2016, The RAND Corporation.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT