Wealth Shock: The Case of Apple in 2018

AuthorLouis Le Guyader
Published date01 April 2019
Date01 April 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/jcaf.22380
EDITORIAL
Wealth Shock: The Case of Apple in 2018
Louis Le Guyader
1|INTRODUCTION
In fiscal 2018, Apple reported over $3.5 billion in securities'
losses. With this, the securities losses on Apple's balance
sheet had accumulated to over $4.3 billion. These losses
were shielded from view by accounting rules that kept them
out of Earnings. On Apple's balance sheet, its securities port-
folio shrunk by this amount as did its equity account. For
various reasons the losses did not reduce the company's
free cash flows.
Such losses are a wealth shock.Wealth shocks are the
down sideof wealth effects. They are losses that map into
a wealth decrease. The losses were not directly caused by
management. These particular shocks arose because external
market interest rates rose. As a result, there was a drop in the
market value of Apple's fixed income securities, its market-
able securities.Since Apple's equity account also
decreased, the wealth decrease is plainly visible.
Wealth shocks of these kinds impact the company's bal-
ance sheet but not its earnings, and not its cash flows. They
deserve special attention in the current economic cycle of
the United States because they are caused by an external fac-
tor, interest rates, that has risen. This article explains why
Apple's shareholders appear to have correctly interpreted the
accounting system's signal and ignored this shock. This arti-
cle will also explain why the shock, using the same set of
signals, likely factored into management's apparent decisions
to allow the securities already held to mature rather than lock
in losses.
2|THE THEORY OF WEALTH
EFFECTS
2.1 |Economic Theory
Economists have described wealth effectsas increased
spending by an affected party that perceives its wealth has
increased. The setting most frequently discussed is that of an
investor who owns a portfolio of assets. The portfolio's
assets are exposed to external price increases. The portfolio
has a higher market value because its assets' values price
have increased. The investor's position appears to have
improvedtheir wealth has increased. Under these circum-
stances, the investor will (or should) spend some of that
increased wealth, at least in theory. And the new spending
should occur even if the appreciated portfolio in question is
not liquidated for that purpose (Cooper & Dynan, 2014).
Economists are not certain if price changes map through
to observable investor behaviors. Documenting the causal
link is daunting. Many dots must be connected. But the the-
ory is workable even with this problem. The economic the-
ory is problematic when the dots connecting increased prices
to wealth increases and consumption increases cannot be
connected. The worst case is one where the simultaneous
increases that should be connected might in fact represent
independent unassociated events. In the worst case, if a posi-
tive correlation can be measured but the causal connection
does not exist, it is a statistical nightmare that is labeled
spurious.
Wealth effect economicsshould apply to all asset clas-
ses, not only assets that can be assembled into portfolios.
That brings us to Apple's fixed income securities. And these
dynamics should be observable even if an intermediary is
placed between the ultimate investor and the asset position.
The intermediary is Apple's accounting system. Shareholders
invest in Apple, and then Apple invests in securities. The
investors only have an indirect interest in the securities as
shareholders of Apple.
Wealth shocks are a special case of wealth effects. As
asset prices decrease, measurable paper wealth decreases.
The decrease in wealth should cause consumption to
decrease. The slowdown in consumption should be corre-
lated to the perception that wealth has declined.
We expect to see the investor impact, or lack thereof, in
Apple's stock price. Since management must husband
company resources, changes in the value of the most liquid
Received: 8 March 2019 Revised: 9 March 2019 Accepted: 11 March 2019
DOI: 10.1002/jcaf.22380
J Corp Acct Fin. 2019;30:712. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jcaf © 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. 7

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT