Voluntary Contributions to a Mutual Insurance Pool

AuthorJONATHAN VAKSMANN,MARIE CLAIRE VILLEVAL,LOUIS LÉVY‐GARBOUA,CLAUDE MONTMARQUETTE
Date01 February 2017
Published date01 February 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12181
VOLUNTARY CONTRIBUTIONS TO A MUTUAL INSURANCE POOL
LOUIS L ´
EVY-GARBOUA
Universit´
e Paris 1 - Panth´
eon Sorbonne
CLAUDE MONTMARQUETTE
Universit´
e de Montr´
eal
JONATHAN VAKSMANN
Universit´
e du Maine
MARIE CLAIRE VILLEVAL
Universit´
edeLyon
Abstract
We study mutual-aid games in which individuals choose to contribute to
an informal mutual insurance pool. Individual coverage is determined
by the aggregate level of contributions and a sharing rule. We analyze
theoretically and experimentally the (ex ante) efficiency of equal and
contribution-based coverage. The equal coverage mechanism leads to
a unique no-insurance equilibrium while contribution-based coverage
develops multiple equilibria and improves efficiency. Experimentally,
the latter treatment reduces the amount of transfers from high contrib-
utors to low contributors and generates a “dual interior equilibrium.”
That dual equilibrium is consistent with the co-existence of different
prior norms which correspond to notable equilibria derived in the the-
ory. This results in asymmetric outcomes with a majority of high con-
tributors less than fully reimbursing the global losses and a significant
Louis L´
evy-Garboua, Universit´
eParis1-Panth
´
eon Sorbonne, Paris School of Economics, Centre
d’´
Economie de la Sorbonne, 106-112 Bd de l’Hˆ
opital, 75647 Paris Cedex 13, France; and Cirano,
Montreal, Canada (Louis.Levy-Garboua@univ-paris1.fr). Claude Montmarquette, CIRANO and
Universit´
edeMontr
´
eal, 2020 rue University, Montreal (Quebec), Canada, H3A 2A5 (Claude.
Montmarquette@cirano.qc.ca). Jonathan Vaksmann, GAINS-TEPP, Universit ´
e du Maine, Facult´
ede
Droit et des Sciences ´
Economiques, Avenue O. Messiaen, 72085 Le Mans Cedex 9, France; and Centre
d’´
Economie de la Sorbonne, Universit´
eParis1-Panth
´
eon Sorbonne (jonathan.vaksmann@univ-
lemans.fr). Marie Claire Villeval, Universit´
e de Lyon, CNRS, GATE 93, chemin des Mouilles, F-69130-
Ecully, France; IZA, Bonn, Germany; Department of Public Finance, University of Innsbruck, Austria
(villeval@gate.cnrs.fr).
We thank Romain Zeiliger for programming the experiment presented in this paper and Nathalie
Viennot for research assistance. Financial support from the Government of Qu´
ebec and the French
Agence Nationale de la Recherche (Inter-SHS program, Convention 04 5 675/50.0520) is gratefully
acknowledged. This research was performed within the framework of the LABEX CORTEX (ANR-11-
LABX-0042) of Universit´
e de Lyon, within the program Investissements d’Avenir (ANR-11-IDEX-007)
operated by the French National Research Agency (ANR). Referees’ comments and suggestions were
very useful in revising the paper. The usual disclaimer applies.
Received March 6, 2013; Accepted September 4, 2015.
C2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 19 (1), 2017, pp. 198–218.
198
Voluntary Contributions 199
minority of low contributors less than fully defecting. Such behavioral
heterogeneity may be attributed to risk attitudes (risk tolerance vs risk
aversion) which is natural in a risky context.
1. Introduction
In spite of the prevalence of assistance and universal insurance in a growing number of
countries, the economic theory of insurance tends to ignore the fact that one’s cover-
age against insurable risk will often not depend solely on one’s own contributions. In
this paper, we wish to examine cases in which individual coverage against risk is deter-
mined by the aggregate level of voluntary contributions in a group and a sharing rule.
We designate this type of insurance scheme as “voluntary mutual aid.” We envision mu-
tual aid here as a unifying concept that can be useful for analyzing various institutions.
Mutual-aid pools offer insurance to members of a specified group, typically sharing a
common characteristic. The homogeneity of members facilitates the full coverage of
independent random losses at fair price and enhances solidarity among members and
their willingness to contribute to the pool. To illustrate this point, Schwindt and Vining
(1998) motivate their proposal for a mutual insurance pool for transplant organs by
the incentive it provides to donate. Group members are free to join and contribute and
they redistribute resources between themselves according to a sharing rule. All mem-
bers are impartially treated and resources are divided between them according to needs
or participation: those who need or participate most are helped most. Mutual-aid orga-
nizations have existed at least since the medieval craft guilds.1Important contemporary
examples of voluntary mutual-aid pool are “climate clubs” of adherents to international
climate policy agreements (Nordhaus, 2015) that offer some kind of mutual insurance
against differential climate change damages and trade unions that provide unionized
workers with protection against employment hazards. However, trade unions and cli-
mate clubs are perfect illustrations of the problem raised by the group’s heterogeneity
to voluntary mutual-aid pools. Workers who didn’t unionize and countries who didn’t
sign the agreement may still benefit from the contributions of unionized workers or
cooperative countries. Thus, a conflict arises between insurance motives and incentives,
which needs to be resolved. For illustration, going back to the proposal of a mutual
insurance pool for transplant organs, Howard (2007) remarks that the pool derives its
efficiency by linking very explicitly the willingness to donate and the ability to benefit
from transplantation and by punishing free riders: persons who refuse to donate but
would gladly accept organs from others.
In contrast with formal mutual insurance schemes in which paying a premium is
contractual, compulsory and excludable,2voluntary contributions and indemnities to
a mutual-aid pool constitute an informal insurance scheme with no contract, no legal
1Friendly Societies were found throughout Europe in the 18th and 19th centuries. During the Great
Depression, the American “fraternity societies” and the English “workers clubs” provided their members
with health insurance. (Almost) complete consumption insurance in small communities (Townsend,
1994) and in large societies (Mace, 1991; Cochrane, 1991; Schulhofer-Wohl, 2011) reveals an efficient
implicit structure of mutual insurance in those groups. Anecdotally, we have been aware of the example
of students contributing to a fund used to reimburse contraveners who have been fined for fare dodging
in public transportation.
2In Barigozzi et al. (2013), mutualization corresponds to participating policies in which policyholders
jointly hold the residual claims on the common pool. Policyholders share the aggregate risk and, af-
ter an initial contribution, contribute whatever amount is needed yearly to meet the losses insured by
the pool (on participating policies. See also Doherty and Dionne, 1993; Smith and Stutzer, 1990, 1995;

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT