Volatility and correlation timing: The role of commodities

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/fut.21939
Published date01 November 2018
Date01 November 2018
Received: 31 October 2017
|
Revised: 14 May 2018
|
Accepted: 14 May 2018
DOI: 10.1002/fut.21939
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Volatility and correlation timing: The role of commodities
Panos K. Pouliasis
|
Nikos C. Papapostolou
Faculty of Finance, Cass Business School,
City, University of London, London, UK
Correspondence
Panos K. Pouliasis, Faculty of Finance,
Cass Business School, City, University of
London, The Costas Grammenos Centre
for Shipping, Trade and Finance, 106
Bunhill Row, London EC1Y 8TZ, UK.
Email: p_pouliasis@city.ac.uk
This paper examines the role of commodities from the perspective of dynamic
asset allocation. We model conditional second moments of stock, bond, and
commodity futures and examine their impact on the portfolio choice decision of
a riskaverse investor in a meanvariance framework. Findings suggest that
adding commodities in the opportunity set enhances portfolio riskreturn
characteristics and offers diversification benefits. Moreover, there is substantial
economic value in both volatility and correlation timing strategies. Results are
robust across various subperiods and rebalancing strategies: alternative
correlation dynamics specifications, shortsale constraints, and transaction
costs under both inand outofsample settings.
KEYWORDS
asset allocation, commodities, volatility timing, correlation timing, multivariate GARCH
JEL CLASSIFICATION
C52, C53, G11, Q02
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Over the last several years, commodity markets have experienced dramatic fluctuations. Significant amounts of funds
allocated to commodity futures and index funds made the sector very popular in the mid2000s among institutional
investors of versatile risk attitudes, either as a pure speculation instrument or as a diversification tool. The statistical
features of commodity returns arise from the underlying demand and supply dynamics, yet the price formation function
across commodities is diverse, and this might result in substantial diversification potential.
Investorsinterest in commodities is primarily motivated by the belief that commodities offer a hedge against
inflation (Bodie, 1983; Edwards & Park, 1996; Irwin & Landa, 1987) and form an alternative asset class that can
bestow diversification gains to investors. In particular, while equity returns tend to be impacted adversely during
periods of inflation, commodity prices increase and, thus, long positions in commodity futures realize profits. This
is consistent with efficient diversification against downturns in traditional assets such as equity and bond markets
(see Büyüksahin, Haigh, & Robe, 2010; Chong & Miffre, 2010; Gorton & Rouwenhorst, 2006). The diversification
benefits of commodities have been examined by Jensen, Johnson, and Mercer (2000), Belousova and Dorfleitner
(2012), and You and Daigler (2013), among others. For example, Bodie and Rosansky (1980) conduct a
comprehensive analysis of 23 individual commodities during the period from 1950 to 1976 and find that by
switching from a stockonly portfolio to one that contained 60% stocks and 40% commodities, investors could have
reduced their risk by 30% without giving up any returns. Georgiev (2001) performs a similar study over the period
19952005 and demonstrates that adding a commodity component to a diversified portfolio leads to enhanced
Sharpe ratios (SR). Similar are the results of Conover, Jensen, Johnson, and Mercer (2010) who report that
commodity exposure improves portfolio returns in periods of increasing interest rates, consistent with the view
that commodities serve as an inflation hedge.
J Futures Markets. 2018;38:14071439. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/fut © 2018 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
1407
Another branch of the literature (e.g., Lombardi & Ravazzolo, 2016; Silvennoinen & Thorp, 2013; Tang & Xiong,
2012) argues that the correlation of commodities with stocks and bonds has strengthened. As such, their effectiveness as
an alternative riskdiversification channel
1
diminishes as a consequence of financialization of the commodity markets.
For example, Daskalaki and Skiadopoulos (2011) challenge their return and risk advantages and find that a mean
variance investor is not better off by allocating a portion of their capital to commodities compared to a portfolio that
consists of traditional assets, consistent with the empirical evidence on the increasing financialization of commodities.
Similarly, Cotter, EyiahDonkor, and Potì (2017) implement different strategies and conclude that commodities do not
improve the opportunity set of an investor with an existing portfolio of stocks, bonds, and Tbills.
Much of the previous research reports mixed evidence on the merits of commodity investment as part of a diversified
portfolio. In essence, these gains are hard to predict and can vary significantly across commodities, throughout time or
with respect to the business cycle. Belousova and Dorfleitner (2012) confirm that there is a strong variation in the
diversification contribution across individual commodities and commodity sectors. This can be attributed to the unique
fundamentals of each commodity sector that makes them uncorrelated with one another. In other words, it is more
meaningful to consider them as a market of separate assets rather than a homogeneous market (e.g., see Erb & Harvey,
2006). In addition, Büyüksahin et al. (2010) find that the alleged benefits that commodities could bring to equity
investors did not materialize when they would have helped the most. This timevariation in the diversification value is
further confirmed by Adams and Glück (2015) who argue that commodities provide less loss protection after 2008. After
the financial crisis, a new channel transmitting stock market shocks to commodities has opened, especially when the
latter exhibit high volatility. In effect, whether commodities add economic value in asset allocation seems to be linked
to the business cycle and market conditions. For example, Gorton and Rouwenhorst (2006) assert that commodities
improve the riskreturn profile of stock and bond portfolios, and the effect can be more pronounced in late expansion
and early recession phases. Furthermore, Jensen et al. (2000) find that during restrictive phases of the monetary cycle,
commodity futures can lead to significant portfolio return enhancement. Finally, Cheung and Miu (2010) also report
that the diversification gains of commodities are regimedependent with the overall longrun benefits being a result of
the infrequent episodes of outbursts in the commodity markets.
Another reason for conflicting results in the literature might be attributed to the various research designs. The
majority of studies analyzing the contribution of commodity investment in a portfolio of traditional assets is based on
an insample setting. However, insample analyzes implicitly entail forwardlooking information and, therefore, tend to
overstate the achievable gains. For example, Daskalaki and Skiadopoulos (2011) find that commodities contribute only
insample, but do not add value outofsample. Bessler and Wolff (2015) test different asset allocation strategies and
report that the attainable benefits of commodities are much smaller than suggested by previous studies and depend on
the type of commodity. Other studies conclude that commodities enhance the outofsample performance of optimized
portfolios (Daskalaki, Skiadopoulos, & Topaloglou, 2017; Gao & Nardari, 2018; You & Daigler, 2013). Given the diverse
conclusions, the outofsample contribution of commodities remains ambiguous; this constitutes an additional
motivation to explore whether the benefits ascribed to commodities have been exaggerated or not, and investigate the
means to practically exploit them.
The aim of this paper is to empirically examine the impacts of considering commodity investments while at the same
time exploit asset volatility and correlation dynamics from the perspective of dynamic portfolio management. We
consider an active portfolio manager who uses forecasts from dynamic volatility and correlation models to rebalance a
portfolio that contains traditional assets (stocks, bonds, and cash) and a pool of 14 commodities traded on the CME
Group as well as a diversified commodity index. To this end, we compare the performance of different models of
forecasting covariances in terms of optimizing meanvariance efficient portfolios: (a) sample covariance, (b) constant
conditional correlation (CCC; Bollerslev, 1990), (c) dynamic conditional correlation (DCC; Engle, 2002), (d) mixed data
sampling conditional correlation (MDC; Colacito, Engle, & Ghysels, 2011), and (e) regime switching dynamic
correlation (RSC; Pelletier, 2006). A more accurate set of volatility and/or correlation predictions will render the
investors a way to adaptively adjust their positions so as to achieve a higher utility level. Our analysis aims to provide
market participants with information that can be used to fine tune risk attitudes and support the decisionmaking
process.
1408
|
POULIASIS AND PAPAPOSTOLOU
1
Silvennoinen and Thorp (2013) present evidence favoring commodity and financial market integration and document that correlations between stock returns and returns to the majority of
commodity futures have increased. This implies that there might be variables with the capacity to predict both commodity and equity returns (e.g., see Hong & Yogo, 2012). For instance, Asness,
Moskowitz, and Pedersen (2013) find common factors able to explain the pooled cross section of various asset classes including commodities. On the contrary, some earlier studiesprior to the
20072009 financial crisis (e.g., Büyüksahin et al., 2010; Chong & Miffre, 2010)challenge the view of increased integration and argue that commodity returns are affected by commodityspecific
variables. Hence, equity asset pricing factors cannot explain the cross section of commodity futures suggesting market segmentation (e.g., Bessembinder & Chan, 1992; Erb & Harvey, 2006).
The contributions of this study are several. First, we revisit the role of commodities in asset allocation and their
capacity to provide diversification benefits in a case study that examines portfolio riskreturn characteristics. Results are
validated in terms of SRs and riskadjusted abnormal realized returns (Modigliani & Modigliani, 1997). Optimal
portfolios derived from either the traditional asset classes alone (equities, bonds, and cash) or augmented with different
commodity investments. More important, we consider both static and several dynamic asset allocation strategies, and,
therefore, offer additional insights; whether or not the portfolio benefits of commodities depend on the implemented
asset allocation approach. In doing so, we investigate individual commodities and a diversified commodity index
separately, thereby evaluating their potential impact from a portfolio management perspective.
Second, we systematically address the issue under the prism of shorthorizon volatility and correlation timing
strategies. This way, asset allocation efficiency, in terms of risk minimization and return maximization, is directly
linked to predictions of volatilities and correlations. To the best of our knowledge, this is one of a few studies that
explicitly takes into account predictability of second moments in forming optimal portfolios. This aspect has been
largely neglected by assetallocation studies that consider commodities that mainly rely on constant historical
estimators (e.g., Belousova & Dorfleitner, 2012; Bodie & Rosansky, 1980; Jensen et al., 2000) or rollingsample
estimators (e.g., Bessler & Wolff, 2015; Daskalaki & Skiadopoulos, 2011). An exception is Gao and Nardari (2018) who
consider dynamic forwardlooking strategies. As it is widely agreed that the covariance structure of asset class returns
varies substantially across periods and market conditions, this might have an effect on the diversification value, which
is itself timevarying.
Third, our analysis focuses not only on whether volatility timing is able to generate economic value compared to a
benchmark strategy but also on any additional value that can be bestowed to the investor when timing both correlations
and volatility. Thus, for the first time to our knowledge, we assess the impact of dynamic correlations separately from
that of volatility and provide a comprehensive analysis of the extent to which dynamic correlations affect optimal
portfolio choice. To capture the tradeoff between risk and return and derive the economic value of dynamic strategies,
we measure the fees meanvariance riskaverse investors will be willing to pay to switch from one model to another
based on the postulated utility gains (performance or switching fee); for applications, see Fleming, Kirby, and Ostdiek
(2001; 2003), Della Corte, Sarno, and Tsiakas (2009), and Chou and Liu (2010), among others.
Forth, we assess the robustness of our conclusions to the choice of parameters such as different specifications for
correlation dynamics, rebalancing frequency, estimation period (subperiods), and transaction costs. We also consider
how sensitive our results are to different investment stylesthat is, whether there is any impact on the diversification
value of commodities if short selling is not permitted. In addition, since existing studies that support the inclusion of
commodities in the opportunity set are mainly based on insample assessments, we also rely on outofsample
performance evaluations. Finally, the meanvariance setting is also contrasted with optimization of alternative risk
measures that focus on tailrisk (conditional valueatrisk [CVaR]).
The structure of the paper is as follows: The next section describes the methodology used to construct optimum
portfolios and quantify volatility and correlation timing gains; Section 3 introduces the econometric methodology and
variancecovariance predictive models; Section 4 presents the data and presents the model estimation results; Section 5
offers the main empirical results on dynamic portfolio management and provides portfolio performance comparisons
based on different models of the conditional second moments; and finally Section 6 concludes the paper.
2
|
OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO SELECTION
In this section, we first formulate the asset allocation problem using meanvariance analysis. Then, we present the
performance evaluation framework. The details of the methodology are as given below.
2.1
|
Asset allocation in a meanvariance framework
Our objective is to determine whether there is economic value in conditioning trading strategies on volatility and
correlation, and if so, which specification works the best. For this reason, the standard Markowitz (1952) meanvariance
portfolio analysis is used. Let +
rt
1
represent the
N
x
1
vector of risky asset returns
,
with conditional expectation
=
++
μ
Er[]
t|t tt
11
and conditional covariance =− −
++
+++
H Erμrμ[( )( ) ]
t|t t t t|t ttt
11
111| . For each date
t
, the investor
constructs portfolios through the following optimization:
POULIASIS AND PAPAPOSTOLOU
|
1409

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT