Vertical Restraints

AuthorRoger Van den Bergh
DOI10.1177/0003603X15625122
Published date01 March 2016
Date01 March 2016
Article
Vertical Restraints: The European
Part of the Policy Failure
Roger Van den Bergh*
Abstract
This article advances several reasons why EU competition policy on vertical restraints has been a
failure. First, the distinction between price and nonprice restraints is inconsistent, since the economic
effects of both practices are similar. Second, EU competition law creates a number of inefficiencies that
cause a negative impact on social welfare; an example is the ban on absolute territorial protection that
does not allow a full protection from free-riding. Third, it is doubtful that the inefficiencies of EU
competition law can be justified by the market integration goal, since the rules may turn out to be
ineffective in reaching this objective. Fourth, EU competition law on vertical restraints has created
negative side effects: it has put an end to experimentation and innovation of competition rules at the
member-state level and induced private interests groups to spend a lot of effort in lobbying national
regulators. The example of resale price maintenance for books serves as an illustration of the latter
problem. Several of the above pitfalls have been indicated by Richard Markovits in his treatise on U.S.
antitrust law and EU competition law. These criticisms are supported in this paper and further
expanded by a discussion of additional errors that have made the EU competition rules on vertical
restraints a policy failure.
Keywords
EU competition law, vertical restraints, block exemption, black list, market integration, harmonization,
resale price maintenance
I. Introduction
Both U.S. antitrust law and EU competition law historically were understood as prohibitions to protect
equally intrabrand competit ion and interbrand competition . The former refers to the competi tion
between distributors offering a branded product of a given manufacturer within a given vertical
structure (production-wholesale-r etail). The latter involves rivalry betw een producers of different
brands: either competition between different vertical structures or in-store competition through multi-
branding. The dominant, even though controversial, story on the competitive effects of vertical
restraints—i.e., agreements between firms active at different levels of the distribution chain—is that
*Erasmus School of Law, Erasmus University
Corresponding Author:
Roger Van den Bergh, Erasmus School of Law, Erasmus University Rotterdam, Rotterdam, 3062 PA, Netherlands.
Email: r.vandenbergh@law.eur.nl
The Antitrust Bulletin
2016, Vol. 61(1) 167-185
ªThe Author(s) 2016
Reprints and permission:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0003603X15625122
abx.sagepub.com
interbrand competition will mitigate any anticompetitive exercise of market power by the manufac-
turer imposing vertical restraints on its distributors. Nevertheless, at times antitrust law has been
hostile to restrictions of intrabrand competition (in particular, resale price maintenance), even in the
absence of anticompetitive effects on interbrand competition.
In spite of several policy shifts, particularly in recent decades, the rules on vertical restraints both in
U.S. antitrust law and EU competition law have not ceased to provoke criticisms from antitrust
practitioners and academic commentators alike. In his remarkable treatise on the economics and the
application and interpretation of both antitrust regimes, Richard Markovits censures U.S. antitrust law
on vertical restraints as a general error of U.S. courts. He advances both ‘‘ends’’ and ‘‘means’’ reasons
why restrictions of intrabrand competition should not be deemed to violate the Sherman Act. Accord-
ing to Markovits, U.S. antitrust law generally allows economic actors to convert the com petitive
advantages they were able to obtain through superior performance into seller surplus in ways that
do not manifest interbrand anticompetitive intent. Also, efforts to restrict the use of intrabrand
restraints will usually not ben efit consumers, as such rules c an be easily circumvented and may
ultimately deprive consumers from presales and postsales services that they desire.
1
Regarding EU
competition law, Markovits advances similar criticisms and asserts that a stricter attitude towards
intrabrand restraints cannot be justified by the goal of achieving market integration, which differenti-
ates EU competition law from U.S. antitrust law.
2
Markovits’s critical view of the EU competition
regime invites comments from European practitioners and scholars.
This article takes up the latter challenge and focuses on the European part of the vertical restraints
policy failure. At the outset, Markovits should be commended for having taken up the effort to discuss
the peculiarities of EU competition law. Sometimes, U.S. scholars seem to regard EU competition law
merely as a copy of U.S. antitrust law or a less interesting study object because of its shorter history. A
common opinion in the U.S. is that competition rules were introduced in Europe after the Second
World War in order to undo the cartelized industry structure of Nazi Germany, whereby the Sherman
Act served as an example. This vision of things neglects that there was a strong tradition of competition
policy in Germany since the 1930s, which originated from the close cooperation of economists and
lawyers at the University of Freiburg. The ensuing ideas of the so-called Ordoliberal School have
exerted a clear impact upon rule-making by the European Courts up until today.
3
For a correct
understanding of EU competition law, ordoliberalism is as important as Chicago economics is for a
proper comprehension of U.S. antitrust case law. Next to the ordoliberal ideas, the political goal of
creating a common (internal) market has shaped EU competition law in ways that differ from U.S.
antitrust law. Interestingly, in spite of their conceptual differences, both legal regimes have made the
mistakes that Markovits forcefully criticizes. Even though the rules have changed over time, a large
part of the antitrust story on both sides of the Atlantic shows persisting worries about restrictions of
intrabrand competition. This has consumed resources away from antitrust practitioners, courts,
enforcement authorities and academic scholars that likely cannot be justified from the perspective
of a welfare maximizing competition policy.
The structure of this article is as follows. After this introduc tion, the first section summarizes
current EU competition law on vertical restraints. The discussion of these rules is somewhat more
elaborate than the relevant chapter in Markovits’s book in order to include additional details that are
needed for a proper assessment of Mar kovits’s criticisms. The next secti ons elaborate the major
1. RICHARD MARKOVITS,ECONOMIC ANALYSIS AND THE INTERPRETATION AND APPLICATION OF U.S. AND E.U. ANTITRUST LAW 84-85
(2014).
2. RICHARD MARKOVITS,supra note 1, at 111.
3. ROGER VAN DEN BERGH &PETER D. CAMESASCA,EUROPEAN COMPETITION LAW AND ECONOMICS:ACOMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE
(2006); Pierre Larouche & Maarten Pieter Schinkel, Continental Drift in the Treatment of Dominant Firms: Article 102
TFEU in Contrast to §2 Sherman Act (TILEC Discussion Paper, 2013-020).
168 The Antitrust Bulletin 61(1)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT