Vertical Integration

AuthorPaul L. Joskow
DOI10.1177/0003603X1205700303
Published date01 September 2012
Date01 September 2012
Subject MatterArticle
Vertical integration
BYPAUL L. JOSKOW*
Oliver Williamson’s work on transaction cost economics, and more
generally on the factors that determine the boundaries between firms
and markets, has provided key insights that have significantly expanded
our understanding of the attributes of transactions and organizations
that lead to vertical integration and vertical contractual relationships
more broadly. Transaction cost–based theories of vertical integration
focus on the implications of incomplete contracts, asset specificity,
information imperfections, incentives for opportunistic behavior, and the
costs and benefits of internal organization. These theories focus on
efforts by firms to mitigate transaction costs and various contractual
hazards that may arise with anonymous spot market transactions by
choosing among alternative organizational and contractual governance
arrangements that can reduce these costs. There is substantial empirical
support for these theories. Property rights–based theories are sometimes
interpreted as formalizing some of Williamson’s work. However, little
empirical work has focused on property rights–based theories per se.
Principal-agent theories of vertical integration that are distinguished
from other organizational theories primarily by assumed differences in
risk aversion between principals and agents and associated moral
hazard problems have also been advanced. They add little to the other
theories and have limited independent empirical support.
THE ANTITRUST BULLETIN:Vol. 55, No. 3/Fall 2010 :545
* President, Alfred P. Sloan Foundation, New York, NY, and Elizabeth &
James Killian Professor of Economics and Management, Massachusetts Insti-
tute of Technology.
AUTHOR’S NOTE: Portions of this essay draw on material in my papers: Asset Specificity
and Vertical Integration, in THE NEW PALGRAVE DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND
LAW 107 (Peter Neuman ed., 1998); Vertical Integration, in HANDBOOK OF NEW
INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS 319 (C. Menard & M. Shirley eds., 2005); and Vertical
Integration, in 1 ISSUES IN ANTITRUST LAW AND POLICY 273 (ABA Section of
Antitrust Law 2008).
© 2010 by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
I. INTRODUCTION
A great deal of Oliver Williamson’s research has focused on
understanding the factors that lead firms to choose internal organiza-
tion (vertical and horizontal integration) instead of market transac-
tions—that is, his work has focused on the factors that determine the
boundaries between firms and markets and the internal organization
of firms—as well as on the factors that lead firms to eschew simple
anonymous spot market transactions in favor of more complex verti-
cal contractual arrangements—what I will refer to in this article as
“nonstandard contractual arrangements.” Williamson’s work and the
work of those that have built on it both theoretically and empirically
have led to fundamental changes in the way we think about vertical
integration and nonstandard contractual arrangements between firms
at different levels of the production and distribution chain. While we
can point to Coase as raising the fundamental questions regarding the
boundaries between firms and markets and the potential role of
largely undefined transaction costs,1it is Williamson who reignited
interest in this perspective, significantly moved the theory forward,
and stimulated an enormous amount of empirical research on these
issues. An important conceptual lesson from Williamson’s work is
that it is not particularly useful to posit a sharp dichotomy between
internal organization, such as vertical integration, and market trans-
actions. Rather, the appropriate conceptual framework recognizes a
continuum of governance arrangements between spot market trans-
actions and internal organization, including combinations of both,
such as dual sourcing.
Of course, Williamson was not the first economist to address
these issues. Understanding the factors that determine which types of
transactions are mediated through markets and which within firms
through vertical and horizontal integration has been an important
subject of theoretical and empirical research in microeconomics for
many years. Moreover, vertical integration and related nonstandard
contractual arrangements (sometimes referred to as “vertical
restraints” in the antitrust policy arena) have historically attracted
considerable attention under U.S. antitrust laws. Surprisingly, how-
546 :THE ANTITRUST BULLETIN:Vol. 55, No. 3/Fall 2010
1Ronald Coase, The Nature of the Firm, 4 ECONOMICA 386 (1937).
ever, most intermediate microeconomics textbooks pay little if any
attention to the causes and consequences of vertical integration
between suppliers of intermediate goods and services (“upstream”)
and the purchasers of those goods and services (“downstream”), and
the typical undergraduate who majors in economics (and perhaps
goes on to law school and later in life becomes a judge) may learn
nothing about vertical integration, the transaction and organizational
factors that affect the boundaries between firms and markets, and
contractual alternatives to spot market transactions.
This article reviews the theoretical and empirical work in micro-
economics that examines the causes and consequences of vertical
integration. I want to emphasize at the outset that there is not and
will never be one unified theory of vertical integration. Moreover,
while some of the literature on vertical integration continues to focus
on a sharp dichotomy between the decision to make internally or buy
through the market, work by Williamson and others working in the
transaction cost economics tradition that he pioneered, teaches us that
in reality these two governance arrangements are polar cases. A com-
prehensive analysis of the underlying causes and consequences of
vertical integration should not only examine the determinants of the
boundaries between firms and markets but also the origins of various
nonstandard contractual arrangements or “hybrid forms” that lie
between simple anonymous spot market transactions and internal
organization. These hybrid forms include various types of long-term
contracts, franchise contracts, nonlinear pricing arrangements, resale
price maintenance (RPM) agreements, requirements contracts, joint
ventures, dual sourcing (partial vertical integration) and others.
Depending on the circumstances, these alternative contractual
arrangements may be perfect or imperfect substitutes for vertical inte-
gration for dealing with problems that may arise as a result of relying
only on simple repeated spot market relationships between upstream
and downstream firms.
Virtually all theories of vertical integration turn in one way or
another on the presence of market imperfections—deviations from
the long list of explicit and implicit assumptions that are associated
with textbook models of perfect competition and anonymous spot
market transactions that are mediated through hypothetical perfectly
VERTICAL INTEGRATION :547

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT