Vertical collusion

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12308
AuthorYaron Yehezkel,David Gilo
Published date01 March 2020
Date01 March 2020
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.51, No. 1, Spring 2020
pp. 133–157
Vertical collusion
David Gilo
and
Yaron Yehezkel
Wecharacterize collusion involvingsecret vertical contracts between retailersand their supplier—
who are all equallypatient (“vertical collusion”). We show such collusion is easier to sustain than
collusion among retailers. Furthermore, vertical collusion can solve the supplier’s inability to
commit to charging the monopoly wholesale price when retailers are differentiated.The supplier
pays retailers slotting allowances as a prize for adhering to the collusive scheme and rejects
contract deviations. In the presence of competing suppliers, vertical collusion can be sustained
using short-term exclusive dealing.
1. Introduction
This article asks what are the features of ongoing collusion involving not only retailers, but
also their joint supplier (all of whom are strategic playerscaring about future profits), and whether
such collusion is more sustainable than collusion among retailers that does not involvea forward-
looking supplier. Retailers (or other intermediaries) would prefer to collude at the expense of
consumers, but competition among them is often too intense to support such collusion. Retailers
typically buy from a joint supplier, where all firms interact repeatedly. The supplier is typically
a strategic player too, who, like retailers, cares about future profits. This raises the question: can
including the supplier in the collusive scheme improvethe prospects of collusion, and if so, how?
We consider an infinitely repeated game involving competing retailers and a joint supplier
(we later extend the model to multiple suppliers). In everyperiod, retailers offer secret, one-period
two-part tariff contracts to the supplier,and then play a game of incomplete information by setting
retail prices without observing the contract offer their rival made to the supplier. All three firms
TelAviv University; gilod@tauex.tau.ac.il, yehezkel@tauex.tau.ac.il.
We thank Ayala Arad, Giacomo Calzolari, Chaim Fershtman, Bruno Jullien, David Myatt (Editor), Markus Reisinger,
Patrick Rey, Tim Paul Thomes, Noam Shamir, Yossi Spiegel, and three anonymous referees as well as participants at
the MaCCI 2016 conference in Mannheim, the CRESSE 2016 conference in Rhodes, the D¨
usseldorf 2017 workshop
on Vertical Chains, The STILE 2017 law and economics workshop, the ALEA 2018 annual meeting, and seminar
participants at Tel-Aviv University, the Hebrew University, the Interdisciplinary Center in Hertzelia, Bar-Ilan University
and the University of Bergamofor helpful comments. We thank the Israeli Science Foundation, the Cegla Institute, the Eli
Hurvitz Institute for Strategic Management and the Henry Crown Institute for Business Research in Israel for financial
assistance and AylaFinberg, Lior Frank, Michael Leshem, Noam Lev, Hadar Shaked Itzkovitz,Yogev Sheffer,Haim Zvi
Yeger and Nofar Yehezkel, for research assistance.
C2020, The RAND Corporation. 133
134 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
have the same discount factor,so that retailers cannot rely on a more patient supplier to assist them
in colluding. As vertical contracts are secret, retailers cannot use observable vertical contracts as
a commitment device in order to raise the retail price.1
We find that the retailers and the supplier can engage in a collusive scheme involving all of
them. We refer to such a scheme as “vertical collusion.” Each of the three firms has a short-run
incentive to deviate from collusion and increase its own current-period profit at the expense of
the other two, yet they collude because they all gain a share of future collusive profits, should
they adhere to the collusive scheme in the current period. The three firms manage to do so even
when retailers are too shortsighted to maintain standard horizontal collusion between themselves.
Hence, vertical collusion is easier to sustain than horizontal collusion.
The collusive mechanism works as follows.In every period, each retailer asks the supplier to
pay the retailer a fixedfee. The fixed fee implicitly rewards the retailer for adhering to the collusive
price in the previous period, and increases the retailers’ future gains from collusion. Retailers
expect that the supplier will continue rewarding them in the future only if they maintain the
collusive scheme. The supplier, for his part, does not agree to pay retailers fixed fees unless they
offer him a higher wholesale price than the one he would receive absent collusion: the supplier
expects that retailers will continue rewarding him in the future with a high wholesale price only
if he maintains the collusive scheme. Hence, the collusive mechanism involves transferring some
of the retailers’ collusive profit in a current period to the supplier (through higher wholesale
prices paid to the supplier), and receiving part of these profits back in the future, conditional on
colluding in the current period. The higher wholesale price, too, has repercussions on the retailers’
incentives to collude: although it lowerstheir profits from deviating from collusion, it also lowers
their profits from colluding. Wederive a general condition under which these repercussions either
further increase, or do not substantially decrease, the retailers’ incentive to collude, and show that
this condition holds at least when retailers are close substitutes.
For vertical collusion to be sustainable, parties need to be induced not to deviate from these
collusive vertical contracts. This is challenging when vertical contracts are secret, because one
retailer does not observe whether the other retailer made a side-deal with the supplier in order
to deviate from collusion. We show that when a retailer attempts to deviate from the collusive
price by offering the supplier a different vertical contract without compensating the supplier, the
supplier rejects the retailer’s offer and refuses to sell him the product. Having to compensate the
supplier to avoid such rejection renders the retailer’s deviation unprofitable.
We then extend the analysis to the case of multiple suppliers competing over selling a
homogeneous product to homogeneous retailers. We show that there is a vertical collusion
equilibrium in which retailers endogenously offer, in every period, to buy exclusively from the
same supplier. Hence, the collusive equilibrium is sustained with single-period exclusive dealing
commitments. The supplier is induced to assist this vertical collusive scheme, because otherwise
he makes no profits, due to intense competition from other suppliers. We assume a retailer can
renegotiate the contract when the supplier informed him, in the form of cheap talk, that the
competing retailer did not offer to buy exclusively from the supplier. We show that the supplier
is induced to reveal the truth.
Our results have several policy implications. In particular, we identify practices that may
have the potential, in appropriate market circumstances, to be harmful to competition. Our results
can be used as a factor that can shed new light on the antitrust treatment of these practices, and
that can be balanced against their possible virtues.
First, the article sheds a new light on exclusive dealing arrangements, where a retailer
promises to buy from a single supplier. We show that exclusive dealing agreements between
1Importantly, exchangeof infor mation among retailers competing in a downstreammarket regarding the terms of
their contracts with a supplier is likely to be an antitrust violation. See Department of Justice/Federal Trade Commission
(2000); European Commission (2011); Federal Trade Commission (2011); OECD (2010); and New Zealand Commerce
Commission (2014).
C
The RAND Corporation 2020.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT