Varieties of Urbanism: A Comparative View of Inequality and the Dual Dimensions of Metropolitan Fragmentation

AuthorKathleen Thelen,Justin Steil,Yonah Freemark
Published date01 June 2020
Date01 June 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/0032329220908966
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329220908966
Politics & Society
2020, Vol. 48(2) 235 –274
© The Author(s) 2020
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0032329220908966
journals.sagepub.com/home/pas
Article
Varieties of Urbanism:
A Comparative View of
Inequality and the Dual
Dimensions of Metropolitan
Fragmentation
Yonah Freemark, Justin Steil, and Kathleen Thelen
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Abstract
A large literature on urban politics documents the connection between metropolitan
fragmentation and inequality. This article situates the United States comparatively to
explore the structural features of local governance that underpin this connection.
Examining five metropolitan areas in North America and Europe, the article identifies
two distinct dimensions of fragmentation: (a) fragmentation through jurisdictional
proliferation (dividing regions into increasing numbers of governments) and (b)
fragmentation through resource hoarding (via exclusion, municipal parochialism, and
fiscal competition). This research reveals how distinctive the United States is in the
ways it combines institutional arrangements that facilitate metropolitan fragmentation
(through jurisdictional proliferation) and those that reward such fragmentation
(through resource-hoarding opportunities). Non-US cases furnish examples of policies
that reduce jurisdictional proliferation or remove resource-hoarding opportunities.
Mitigating the inequality-inducing effects of fragmentation is possible, but policies
must be designed with an identification of the specific aspects of local governance
structures that fuel inequality in the first place.
Keywords
inequality, fragmentation, metropolitan governance, local politics, resource hoarding
Corresponding Author:
Yonah Freemark, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 77 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge, MA
02139, USA.
Email: freemark@mit.edu
908966PASXXX10.1177/0032329220908966Politics & SocietyFreemark et al.
research-article2020
236 Politics & Society 48(2)
Between 2002 and 2017, the number of local government units in the United States
increased by more than 2,500.1 Some of these local governments incorporated as new
municipalities or seceded from larger school districts to form wealthier, whiter districts.
These events are part of a long-standing trend toward jurisdictional proliferation in
many metropolitan areas. The trend accelerated in the late nineteenth and twentieth
centuries, and especially since the 1970s, as suburbs incorporated to avoid being sub-
sumed within larger cities that featured more socially heterogeneous populations and
lower-income households.2 Thus, for instance, the wealthy Brookline suburb is sur-
rounded on three sides by the city of Boston, having successfully resisted annexation
since 1873; University Park, with one of Texas’s best-performing school districts, is
entirely encircled by Dallas and has tenaciously defended its autonomy since 1945; in
the San Francisco Bay Area, Piedmont, once known as the “City of Millionaires,”
resisted annexation by Oakland in 1897 and in 2013 installed cameras with license plate
readers at city entry points, purportedly to combat “spillover” crime.3 The power to
construct and maintain jurisdictional boundaries is frequently deployed by affluent
communities to hoard resources at the expense of their less affluent neighbors. In the
words of a leader in an effort to detach three of the highest-performing schools from the
county school district that includes Chattanooga, Tennessee, “local control is power.”4
Major metropolitan areas throughout the rich democracies exhibit patterns of spa-
tial inequality, but the politics of metropolitan fragmentation and the extent to which
they entrench or mitigate these inequalities vary widely. Like Boston and San
Francisco, the London and Paris metropolitan areas contain a large number of separate
jurisdictions. Moreover, a wave of reforms beginning in the 1980s delegated signifi-
cant new powers and responsibilities to those European localities. Sometimes intro-
duced under the banner of “new public management,” the British and French
governments designed those reforms to increase administrative efficiency and enhance
local control over service delivery.5 The devolution of powers, however, did not
unleash the same intense resource-hoarding dynamics that are commonplace in the
United States. Indeed, in some cases they inspired actions such as municipal mergers.
The words of a French mayor who agreed to join a neighboring city in a new munici-
pality stand in striking contrast to those of the Chattanooga leader quoted above: “We
are stronger when we are together.”6
Across the rich democracies, cities are important sites of political contestation over
crucial issues of economic redistribution and social opportunity. The contributions of
local politics to national-level differences in inequality and poverty are undisputed.
Yet the literature on cities in comparative political economy remains underdeveloped
as a result of a continued emphasis on national-level institutions and political dynam-
ics. Meanwhile, although there is a large and rich literature on US urban politics,
comparisons to other rich democracies are rare.7
This article situates the US case in a comparative perspective to isolate the features
of local governance that support the resource-hoarding dynamics that are so character-
istic of its local politics—and to identify some of the institutions and the mechanisms
through which other rich democracies reduce those dynamics. No rich democracy
escapes the problems of spatial inequality that characterize metropolitan life, and yet
Freemark et al. 237
the degree to which municipal boundaries are associated with highly unequal policy
packages and public services is particularly pronounced in the United States. Indeed,
the strategies commonly deployed by affluent US communities to separate them-
selves—administratively and fiscally—from their less affluent neighbors are virtually
unthinkable in many other industrialized democracies. A comparative perspective thus
offers a fresh angle on the possibilities and pitfalls of local control, providing new
insights by allowing us to consider variation in the structure of local governance—
varieties of urbanism—and the relationship of that variation to metropolitan growth
and its inequality-generating effects.8
We argue that to understand the relationship between local government structure
and economic inequality, metropolitan “fragmentation” must be understood in at least
two dimensions and considered separately across multiple policy arenas.9 The first
dimension of fragmentation (and the common understanding of the term) is the divi-
sion of a metropolitan area into many municipalities surrounding a central city; we
refer to this as jurisdictional proliferation. The ability to form and maintain small
jurisdictions is determined by legally defined capacities to incorporate, annex, and
secede, as well as by the ability to create so-called special purpose authorities. Such
capacities already distinguish the United States from many of its peers.
Evidence from other advanced industrial countries, however, demonstrates that the
number of separate local governments does not in itself produce inequality. Moreover,
examples from abroad suggest that institutional structures can either incentivize juris-
dictional proliferation or discourage such municipal boundary drawing. We show that
the returns to jurisdictional proliferation depend crucially on the availability of oppor-
tunities for resource hoarding—the second dimension of metropolitan fragmentation.
Comparative analysis thus reveals how distinctive the United States is in the way it
combines institutional arrangements that facilitate metropolitan fragmentation
(through jurisdictional proliferation) and those that reward such fragmentation
(through opportunities for resource hoarding).
Comparative analysis also yields new insights into the dynamics through which
jurisdictional proliferation and resource hoarding become entrenched—but also how
they can be reversed. The US experience suggests that inequality-promoting features
of metropolitan institutions often deepen gradually through largely hidden processes
of change—drift and conversion—when, for example, municipal boundaries are held
in place even as populations shift (drift) or when the redrawing of boundaries turns
otherwise progressive property taxes into regressive revenue structures (conversion).10
Other countries provide examples of measures designed to reverse jurisdictional pro-
liferation or limit its negative impacts. In the cases we consider here, changes to either
of the dual dimensions of metropolitan fragmentation have required overt political
reforms, in some cases following a transition in political power or in other cases rep-
resenting a technocratic response to perceived inefficiencies or inequality.
In addressing these issues through a comparative lens, our analysis engages a long-
standing debate on the merits of local control. Some scholars take a sanguine view of
local governance as promoting responsiveness by bringing the state “closer” to its
constituents, thus improving service delivery and tailoring policy to local conditions.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT