Valuing supply‐chain responsiveness under demand jumps

Published date01 July 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1016/j.jom.2018.06.002
Date01 July 2018
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Valuing supply-chain responsiveness under demand jumps
Is¸ık Biçer
1
| Verena Hagspiel
2
| Suzanne de Treville
3
1
Schulich School of Business, York
University, Toronto, Canada
2
Department of Industrial Economics and
Technology Management, Norwegian
University of Science and Technology,
Trondheim, Norway
3
Faculty of Economics and Business,
Swiss Finance Institute, University of
Lausanne, Lausanne, Switzerland
Correspondence
Suzanne de Treville, Faculty of Economics
and Business, Swiss Finance Institute,
University of Lausanne, 1015 Lausanne,
Switzerland.
Email: suzanne.detreville@unil.ch
Handling Editor: Daniel Guide
Abstract
Asthetimebetweenthedecisionaboutwhattoproduceandthemomentwhen
demand is observed (the decision lead time) increases, the demand forecast becomes
more uncertain. Uncertainty can increase gradually in decision lead time, or can
increase as a dramatic change in median demand. Whether the forecast evolves
gradually or in jumps has important implications for the value of responsiveness,
whichwemodelasthecostpremiumworthpayingtoreducethedecisionleadtime
(the justified cost premium). Demand uncertainty arising from jumps rather than
from constant volatility increases the justified cost premium when an average jump
increases median demand, but decreases the justified cost premium when an aver-
age jump decreases median demand. We fit our model to two data sets, first publicly
available demand data from Reebok, then point-of-sale data from a supermarket
chain. Finally, we present two special cases of the model, one covering a sudden loss
of demand, and the other a one-time adjustment to median demand.
KEYWORDS
cost-differential frontier, demand modeling, fourier analysis, jump-diffusion process, lead-time
reduction
1|INTRODUCTION
Postponing an order quantity decision until demand is
knownthus reducing the decision lead time to zero
eliminates demand-risk exposure.
1
Conversely, demand-
risk exposure tends to increase in the decision lead time,
resulting in stockouts or overstocks that generate mismatch
costs. The ability to postpone the decision about what to
order so that the order quantity can be based on better
demand information can be conceptualized as a real option
(de Treville & Trigeorgis, 2010), and that option's value can
be estimated using quantitative-finance methods. Being
able to quantify the value of reducing demand-uncertainty
exposure that arises from an increase in the decision lead
time transforms time into a decision variable.
The first step in estimating option value is to specify the
forecast-evolution process: how demand uncertainty increases
in decision lead time.
2
The simplest case is the random-walk
assumption that underlies the Black-Scholes option-pricing
model (Black & Scholes, 1973). Each instant that the deci-
sion lead time increases, demand uncertainty increases by a
minute amount following a geometric Brownian motion.
When this constant-instantaneous-volatility process holds,
demand is lognormally distributed with volatility increasing
in the square root of the decision lead time. This assumption
underlies the Cost-Differential Frontier decision tool pro-
posed by de Treville, Schurhoff, Trigeorgis, and Avanzi
(2014) that estimates the cost differential that must be
offered by a long-lead-time supplier to compensate for the
increase in demand-uncertainty exposure resulting from an
increase in decision lead time.
3
In practice, changes in demand may occur suddenly
as a change in median demand ( jump) rather than as an
instantaneous increase in volatility. Demand is frequently
subject to jumps: The World Economic Forum in its 2012
[Note: This article was retypeset after publication in an issue. Due to a
difference in final page count, this PDF has been left unpaginated.
Please refer to the How to Cite box following the references for correct
citation information.]
DOI: 10.1016/j.jom.2018.06.002
J Oper Manag. 2018;4667. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/joom © 2018 APICS 1
report on supply-chain risk attributed 44% of supply-
chain disruptions to demand shocks (World Economic
Forum, 2012).
4
In finance, the limitations of the Black-
Scholes model are well known, but the model is generally
used as a reasonable approximation (e.g., Bakshi, Cao, &
Chen, 1997). When the true forecast-evolution process is
subject to jumps but the mismatch cost is estimated
assuming that all demand uncertainty emerges from a
constant-volatility process, how bad is the error? Does
the constant-volatility version of the model give a good
enough approximation of the mismatch cost for practical
purposes, or does the error impact decision making
enough to warrant the use of a more complex model?
To address this question, we extend the Cost-
Differential Frontier decision tool to include jumps fol-
lowing the classic model proposed by Merton (1976). We
use publicly available demand data from Reebok to gain
insight into how the choice of model impacts supply-
chain decision making. Parsons (2004) studied the cost of
demand-risk exposure faced by Reebok in the context of
the exclusive license held during the period 20002010 to
produce replica jerseys with the National Football League
(NFL, see also Graves & Parsons, 2005).
5
Available publi-
shed Reebok data include the mean and SD of annual
demand for replica jerseys for New England Patriots fans;
price, cost, and residual value; and a qualitative descrip-
tion of the many types of demand jumps observed by
Reebok. Parsons (2004, pp. 7475) concluded his analysis
of Reebok data by proposing that perhaps the single
greatest opportunity for Reebok is to improve its ability
to respond to shifts in demand through shorter lead
times.These data are used by Parsons (2004), Graves
and Parsons (2005), and Parsons and Graves (2005) to
demonstrate the value of postponement. Cattani, Dahan,
and Schmidt (2008) cited this work as exemplifying the
importance of analyzing the value of responsiveness (see
also Uppala, 2016). The decision by the authors of the
Reebok study to make their data and analysis publicly
available made it possible for us to build directly on their
work and use our model to extend their analysis.
Our first result is that the impact of jumps on the cost
premium worth paying to reduce decision lead time
depends on whether a jump is expected to increase or
decrease median demand. If a jump is expected to
increase median demand, then treating demand uncer-
tainty as though it came from a constant-volatility pro-
cess results in an understatement of the justified cost
premium. If, however, a jump is expected to reduce
median demand, then assuming a constant-volatility pro-
cess will lead to an overstatement of that cost premium.
This result arises from how the jump changes the skew-
ness of the marginal demand density. Jumps that are
expected to increase median demand will increase skew-
ness as long as they occur relatively rarely.
6
The resulting
increase in right-tail weight increases the value of the
option to postpone the production commitment. A
jump that reduces median demand reduces skewness,
making the postponement option less valuable. Man-
agers with whom we have reviewed this result have
found it counterintuitive, as they experience more con-
cern about being stuck with excess inventory if a nega-
tive jump occurs than about stocking out following a
positive jump.
In order to make the analysis as useful as possible to
practitioners, we explore two special cases of jumps that
are frequently encountered in practice. The first special
case models the risk that demand would be completely
lost. In the Reebok case, this corresponds to a change of
team jersey that reduces demand for the old model to
zero. We show that adding any reasonable risk of
demand loss to a constant-volatility process substantially
increases the justified cost premium. The second special
case models a one-time update of median demand such
as occurs when decision makers obtain early-sales data,
which we use to quantify the impact of a possible Super-
Bowl win on the cost premium worth paying to reduce
decision lead time. These results are not surprising in
their direction, but they are striking in their magnitude.
When the jumps that everyone knows to exist are explic-
itly considered in setting the decision lead time, the com-
pany is likely to much more aggressively reduce decision
lead time.
A question that arose during the research project
was whether demand jumps are experienced in supply
chains. To address this question, we randomly selected
two products from a supermarket chain and analyzed
100 observations of daily demand from point-of-sale
data, then counted how many observations had stan-
dardized residuals more than three SDsfromzero.The
first product had four such outliers, indicative of
demand jumps, and the second had none. We then con-
sidered what would happen if we forced a jump model
on a product where it seemed like a constant-volatility
assumption would suffice. By moving the threshold
defining outliers from the usual three down to 2.52
SDs, the number of outliers for the second product
increased from zero to four. Interestingly, treating
these four points as jumps rather than normal varia-
tion for the second product substantially increased the
cost-premium frontier. Which representation is correct?
Our model cannot say. But, the fact that the option value
of responsiveness is quite sensitive to when outliers are
assumed to represent demand jumps indicates that this is
an area that managers should be pondering.
2BIÇER ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT