UN Security Council Elections as an Incentive for Compliance

Published date01 November 2023
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/00220027231153575
AuthorJohann Caro-Burnett,Eric Weese
Date01 November 2023
Subject MatterArticles
Article
Journal of Conf‌lict Resolution
2023, Vol. 67(10) 19591992
© The Author(s) 2023
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/00220027231153575
journals.sagepub.com/home/jcr
UN Security Council Elections
as an Incentive for Compliance
Johann Caro-Burnett
1
and Eric Weese
2
Abstract
Standard economic theory would predict that costly demands placed by the United
Nations on its members should be rewarded. Similarly, when rewards are not at-
tractive enough, countries are not expected to comply with such demands. In this
paper, we study whether the rewards offered by the United Nations are seats at the
Security Council. We show empirically that countries that have greater demands
placed upon them by Security Council resolutions are more likely to be elected.
Furthermore, although countries comply with resolutions leading up to their election,
compliance decreases after they are elected. Finally, we show that countries that have
not been in the Security Council recently, and thus are due for election, have additional
requests made of them.
Keywords
civil war resolutions, self-enforcing agreements, election incentives
Introduction
The main goal of the United Nations(UN) Security Council (SC) is to promote
international peace.
1
There are currently almost 100,000 peacekeepers, who have been
deployed among 14 different operations through Security Council resolutions. The
Security Council has also authorized intervention such as the 1990 Gulf War. Since
1
Hiroshima University and Network for Education and Research on Peace and Sustainability,
Higashihiroshima, Japan
2
Institute of Social Science, The University of Tokyo, Japan
Corresponding Author:
Johann Caro-Burnett, Hiroshima University, 1-5-1 Kagamiyama, Higashihiroshima 739-8511, Japan.
Email: johanncb@hiroshima-u.ac.jp
1966, the Security Council has consisted of f‌ive permanent members (P5) and ten non-
permanent members chosen by elections from regional groups.
2
Every year, the SC votes on resolutions to address international conf‌lict. According
to the UN Charter, General Assembly (GA) resolutions are merely recommendations,
while SC resolutions are meant to be binding.
3
Thus, even though votes at the GA can
be useful for estimating preferences and alliances, decisions made at the SC are a better
way to study the degree of cooperation.
4
Although there may be disagreement on
whether SC resolutions fully accomplish its goals, there is no doubt that the UN has
played a role in maintaining peace by deploying peacekeepers, calling for sanctions
(e.g. embargos), and working as a mediator.
Enforcement of SC resolutions relies on the voluntary participation of member
states, and thus these members must have an incentive to implement such resolutions.
5
Theoretically, it is diff‌icult to rationalize cooperation between nations with only
sanctions; thus, some reward is needed. Models of this form for international orga-
nizations (IOs) have been studied, where the reward is voting powerin an organi-
zation that decides whether to take actions that may favor its members (Caro-Burnett,
2022;Maggi and Morelli, 2006).
There are potentially several different conf‌igurations to distribute voting power.
Caro-Burnett (2022) f‌inds that in certain scenarios the best way to provide incentives to
the members of an IO, say the UN, is to elect a subset of countries to a voting council.
Rather than representing an aggregate of countries, the council is elected as a reward for
engaging in costly demands imposed by the UN.
6
Moreover, although it is true that the
GA and SC are separate UN organs from a legal/institutional perspective, we argue that
they may have an implicit understanding at least during SC elections. This is different
from saying that the GA and SC, as entities, have the same preferences; indeed, both of
them represent (in different ways) the preferences of all UN member nations. What we
mean is that the mechanism that ensures countriesengagement in costly demands
dictates that the member nations use their votes (at the GA) to elect to the SC those
members who should be rewarded.
7
Indeed, supporting our argument, most of the
elections to the SC are lightly contested or not contested at all. Moreover, countries that
may seem like the bad actorscan access power, in certain years, to ensure some degree
of cooperation from them.
8
For example, in the Anecdotal Motivation Section, we
discuss the 1993 election of Rwanda and the 2002 election of Angola, both of them
being uncontested elections and following civil wars.
In this paper, we use econometric tools to test an unconventional interpretation of SC
elections. Namely, we test whether there is an implicit game being played between the
UN members, where certain members have to occasionally be elected to the SC in order
to enforce their cooperation.
9
More specif‌ically, we analyze empirically the dynamics
between the key equilibrium variables that represent voting power, incentives, and
rewards. Broadly speaking, the implicit games equilibrium dictates that countries are
requested to comply with costly resolutions, and after observing some evidence of
compliance, the UN rewards some of those countries with SC seats. Moreover, we
provide the f‌irst quantitative examination of compliance with UNSC resolutions. In
1960 Journal of Conf‌lict Resolution 67(10)
addition, we examine the number of resolutions naming a particular country and the
depth of the demands that are made upon each country. Our main empirical tools are
conditional logit and ordinary least squares. Our main data set is the International Peace
Institutes (IPI) compliance data on SC resolutions.
As our f‌irst result, we show that countries that have greater demands placed upon
them are more likely to be elected to the SC, which is in line with theoretical pre-
dictions.
10
We then move beyond those theoretical predictions, and show two more
results that enhance and extend the existing stylized mathematical models. Our second
and third results show that countries are less likely to comply with resolutions after
having been elected, and there are more resolutions requesting cooperation in years
when countries are due for election.
To address endogeneity,our identif‌ication strategy is an event study framework. The
change in countriesbehavior before and after their election to the SC (our second
result) provides an important source of variation to justify the causal model that we
based our hypothesis tests on. If, contrary to our assumptions, countries have demands
placed upon them by the SC because they are the naturally cooperativetype of
country, and they are then elected by the SC because they are this type of country, then
we would not expect their behavior to change after their election. By looking at
compliance with SC resolutions before and after election to the council, we show that,
after election, countries that were previously cooperative shirk on their obligations.
11
Moreover, this phenomenon is not exclusive to the UN, as we can see similar shirking
behavior in other IOs such as the European Union (EU) and the World Trade Or-
ganization (WTO).
12
On the other hand, the above discussion does not contradict Voeten (2014),who
f‌inds that joining the SC leads to becoming a more cooperative member of the
organization. In that study, cooperation is understood (for the UN case) as
peacekeeping contributions, which are factors not usually discussed explicitly in
SC resolutions. In our study, cooperation is referred to compliance with resolu-
tions, which are supposed to represent the decisions made at the core of the
organization.
Our results extend the existing empirical literature on the SC. Vree lan d and
Dreher (2014),Dreher et al. (2014),andSchmitz and Schwarze (2012) analyze
the determinants of SC elections. We pay particular attention to Vreeland and
Dreher (2014)sturn-taking variable, which indicates that the longer a country is
not elected, the more likely it is to become a member of the SC. In our study, we
combine the Vreeland and Dreher (2014) data with the data on SC resolutions
from IPI and show that countries that have not been elected recently, and are thus
due for election,are likely to have additional demands placed upon them by
the SC.
The remainder of the paper has the following structure: f‌irst, we provide brief
concrete examples that are aligned with our theory and are within our period of
analysis. Next, we discuss the theoretical justif‌ication for our study. We then discuss the
data, and f‌inally we show our results.
Caro-Burnett and Weese 1961

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT