Two Models of Ownership: How Commons Has Co‐Existed with Private Property

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12147
AuthorDavid Tabachnick
Date01 March 2016
Published date01 March 2016
Two Models of Ownership: How Commons
Has Co-Existed with Private Property
By DAVI D TABACHNICK*
ABSTRACT. This article challenges the claim by many historians that the
rise of capitalism requires the destruction of common property systems.
In contrast to the English case in which commons were enclosed, French
peasants used their common property system to regulate the market,
provide a rural safety net and a democratic check on elites, while urban
industry developed. European battles over common property replayed
in surprising ways in colonial African countries such as Sierra Leone, and
echoes reemerge today. The West African country of Guinea tests two
possible paths to development of a market society: the English path and
the French path. Interviews with key government officials collected in
1993 help explain why Guinea, despite adopting a land law in 1992
inspired by the English path, has so far failed to widely apply the law
and, in fact, is following the French path. The United States pursued a
policy of replacing American Indian common property systems with
exclusive individual property rights. Nonetheless, Indian common
property survives in the form of recent recognition of Indian off-
reservation hunting and fishing rights. The Menominee reservation
successfully resisted the destruction of its common property system and
today participates in the market in a manner that preserves reservation
ecology, democratic government, and Menominee cultural identity.
Rethinking the meaning of French, African, and U.S. accommodation to
common property systems offers important lessons for contemporary
development policies in Africa and around the world.
Introduction
What did the global spread of a Western system of real property, from
about the 16
th
century forward, mean for local common property
*David Tabachnick is Associate Professor and Chair of the Sociology Department at
Muskingum University and a member of the Wisconsin Bar. He thanks the students
of his sociology of law class for their lively discussions of the ideas in this article.
American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 75, No. 2 (March, 2016).
DOI: 10.1111/ajes.12147
V
C2016 American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc.
cultures and community governance of land and people in England
and France and subsequently for local indigenous peoples in the
United States and Africa? In this article, I will explore the answer to this
question and challenge the canonical myth that has characterized a nar-
row, rigid idea of Western law and economics as a necessary step
towards capitalism or a modern market society. How is it that a false
and misleading story about the birth of capitalism became so pervasive
that people who disagree about all kinds of things nonetheless agree
on one thing: capitalism arises out of the destruction of common prop-
erty systems?
Central to the story is the conflict between two types of property
rights: 1) common property rights and 2) exclusive property rights. A
common property system is one in which property rights are con-
strained by overlapping group rights. This constraint requires the mem-
bers of a group to agree on activities that affect group property rights.
An exclusive property rights system is the opposite of a common prop-
erty system. In this case property rights are not constrained by overlap-
ping group property rights, which means that a property holder can
exclude others from it. However, in a system of exclusive rights, holders
of property rights nonetheless are always constrained by some level of
government regulatory power. A property rights holder can be either
an individual personor a legal entity, such as a corporation.
I start with a discussion of the enclosing of the commons in England
and the rise of Anglo-American concepts of exclusive property rights,
contract, and local community governance. In France, by comparison,
a coalition of French peasants, church authorities, gentry, and other
elites effectively resisted imposition of an English-style real property
system that excluded overlapping group property rights. In France, a
modern market society developed during the 19
th
century in a manner
that largely accommodated the rural common property system, despite
repeated attempts by state authorities to abolish common property.
Nonetheless, colonial and contemporary France have been thoroughly
dominated by the myth of capitalism as the scourge of common prop-
erty. English and French colonies sometimes confronted, sometimes
accommodated, African common property systems. I sketch a picture
of Anglophone and Francophone Africa, with special attention to Nige-
ria, Sierra Leone, and Guinea. Debates among government officials in
Two Models of Ownership 489
Guinea, after the reform of its land laws in 1992, return to themes in
French and English history. The myth that a modern market society
requires the destruction of “pre-modern” common property systems
has also dominated the relationship between the United States and
American Indians. England’s attack on its commoners and early ideolo-
gists of English colonialism in America, such as John Locke, greatly
influenced Americans. However, Americans at times have acknowl-
edged the rights of American Indians to govern themselves in common
property systems that, as the example of the Menominee will show, can
succeed in a modern market society.
The enclosing of the commons in England was not merely a physical
process of putting up fences but also a conceptual process that created
a new legal, economic,and sociological reality. The commons provided
the basis for local community governance and access by all residents to
land and resources. As commons were enclosed, preexisting systems of
group rights and overlapping community member property rights were
suppressed and property rights were largely consolidated by individual
property owners. The property rights holder always remained subject
to some degree of community governance and, thus, to group limita-
tion of exclusive property rights.
The belief in property rightsthat exclude overlapping group property
rights became part of an emerging ideology of individualism in the 17
th
and 18
th
centuries. There certainly was no concept of exclusive prop-
erty rights among Africans or American Indians. When the latter cul-
tures encountered Europeans who held extremely individualistic views
of property, an epic struggle ensued, which has still notbeen resolved.
Western property systems that are based on exclusive rights have
been forcibly imposed or willingly adopted in instances, but Africans
and American Indians have also at times successfully resisted such
imposition or adoption. In some instances, the process of reducing
overlapping property rights to a unitary holder of exclusive property
rights has been challenged effectively. The West is then forced to
remember its own history, resurrecting a form of overlapping property
rights reminiscent of English communities before the enclosing of the
commons. For example, American Indians have successfully forced
American states to negotiate regulation of off-reservation hunting, fish-
ing, and gathering rights that overlap non-Indian property. Modern
The American Journal of Economics and Sociology490

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT