Transactional Torts

AuthorEric E. Johnson
Pages530-577
530
30. Transactional Torts
“In business, sir, one has no friends, only correspondents.”
Alexandre Dumas
Introduction
In this chapter we look at torts that arise in the context of business
transactions. These are often called “business torts,” although
businesses deal with all torts, from negligence to defamation. What
makes these torts unique is that they are tied to deals and transactions
the business of business, if you like. We will see buyers suing sellers,
lawyers suing accountants, and sports agents suing sports agents. As
opposed to the personal injury torts we have been exploring, the
primary harm here is economic. But that is not to say things don’t get
personal. Transactional-tort cases frequently involve a surprising
amount of spite and pique something you will see in the cases
below.
There are a variety of causes of action that could fall under the
umbrella of transactional torts, but this chapter covers a few
particularly important ones: intentional economic interference, fraud,
and breach of fiduciary duty. They are all torts that pick up where
contract law leaves off in defining the legal landscape for conducting
commerce.
For all transactional torts, it is important to keep in mind the
overarching default rule: Where the gravamen of the plaintiff’s
complaint is that a contract has been breached, then the plaintiff’s
only remedy is breach of contract. Tort law is not supposed to
interfere in the contractual context at least not unless the rationale
is highly compelling. But that is not to say that these torts are
infrequently alleged. For plaintiffs in business disputes, tort law has
great allure. Tort law’s concepts of compensatory damages are more
expansive than those under contract law. Plus, for real bad apples,
there is the possibility of punitive damages. And business disputes
often turn up bad apples. Also, plaintiffs going to trial on a tort may
531
benefit from a strategic advantage. In a regular contract dispute,
evidence that makes the defendant look bad is likely to be irrelevant,
and therefore inadmissible. But if a tort is alleged, the plaintiff’s
lawyers may be able to put before the jury all sorts of disparaging
evidence because it is relevant to showing tortious intent.
Because of these advantages, plaintiffs are always looking for ways to
tortify contract disputes. And that means courts are always looking
for ways to keep this drive toward tortification from getting out of
hand. In fact, one theme that runs through the doctrines of
intentional economic interference, fraud, and breach of fiduciary
duty, is the existence of safeguards put into the doctrine that are
meant to prevent workaday contract disputes from morphing into
mudslinging tort litigation.
Intentional Economic Interference
The idea behind the cause of action for intentional economic
interference is that a person should be free to seek economic
opportunities without being impeded by intermeddling ne’er-do-
wells.
Suppose I manage to get a contract with my neighbors to mow their
lawn something that will give me enough cash to go to the movies
and buy a few new video games. Yet you just because you want to
see me fail work to destroy my nascent lawn mowing business, and
you manage to cause my neighbors to terminate my services.
At this point, I can sue you for intentional economic interference.
But we should stop to wonder why I would need such a cause of
action to sue you. Most of the things you could do to sabotage me
are already tortious. For instance, you could tell lies about me that
would cause my neighbor to fire me. You could steal my lawn
mower. Or you could put sugar in the mower’s gas tank. If you do all
that to me, I can sue you for intentional economic interference, but I
can also sue you for defamation, trespass to chattels, and conversion.
So the question is, why does tort law need an independent cause of
action for intentional economic interference?
532
The true value of the intentional economic interference tort shows its
worth when something particularly sneaky is afoot. Say you convince
your little brother and sister to go over to play with the neighbors
kids and convince them to host an elaborate tea party on the lawn
during what you know to be the only hours I have free to get the
mowing done. Let’s say you do this two weeks in a row, at which
point the neighbors terminate my services because I’m not getting the
job done. In such a situation, I would have no claim for trespass,
conversion, or defamation, but my claim for intentional economic
interference will let me in the courthouse doors.
Instead of having a single tort of “intentional economic
interference,” many jurisdictions have two causes of action: the tort
of intentional interference with contract and the separate tort of
intentional interference with prospective economic advantage.
Both torts are essentially the same, except that with the former, there
is a contract between the plaintiff and a third party. With the later,
there would have been a contract but for the defendant’s actions.
Here is a statement of the blackletter rule for intentional economic
interference:
A plaintiff can establish a prima facie case for
intentional economic interference by
showing: (1) there is a valid contract or non-
speculative economic expectancy between the
plaintiff and a third party; (2) the defendant had
knowledge of this economic interest; (3) the
defendant intended to interfere with this
economic interest; (4) but for the interference,
the plaintiff would have received the benefit of
the economic interest; and (5) the plaintiff
thereby accrued damages.
These elements are mostly self-explanatory, but a few observations
should be made.
First, it bears emphasis that the economic interest (the contract or
prospective economic advantage) must arise between the plaintiff and
a third party that is, someone who is not the defendant. If the
defendant backs out of a contract, the remedy is breach of contract.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT