Trading activities, productivity and markups: Evidence for Spanish manufacturing

AuthorJuan A. Máñez Castillejo,María E. Rochina Barrachina,Juan A. Sanchis Llopis,Consuelo Mínguez Bosque
Published date01 March 2020
Date01 March 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12892
644
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/twec World Econ. 2020;43:644–680.
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Received: 12 June 2019
|
Accepted: 11 September 2019
DOI: 10.1111/twec.12892
SPECIAL ISSUE ARTICLE
Trading activities, productivity and markups:
Evidence for Spanish manufacturing
Juan A.Máñez Castillejo1,2
|
ConsueloMínguez Bosque3
|
María E.Rochina Barrachina1,2
|
Juan A.Sanchis Llopis1,2
1University of Valencia, Valencia, Spain
2ERICES, Valencia, Spain
3IVIE, Valencia, Spain
Funding information
Secretaría de Estado de Investigación, Desarrollo e Innovación, Grant/Award Number: ECO2017‐86793‐R
KEYWORDS
exports, firm‐level data, imports of intermediates, manufacturing, markups, output prices, total factor productivity
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The liberalisation of international trade has had an important impact on firms' internationalisation
strategies and on the internationalisation of production processes through the incorporation of im-
ported goods in the value chain. These trends mean an impulse to the intensification of exports and
to the improvement of local production through imports of intermediate inputs, which could enhance
firms' productivity and profits ultimately.
This paper aims to contribute to the international trade literature by exploring firms trading strate-
gies and their impact on firms' productivity and markups. In particular, we focus on firms' imports of
intermediates and export strategies, and analyse the dynamic links between them and their impact on
productivity and markups.1
Thus, the first strand of the international trade literature we seek to contribute is the analysis of
the dynamic linkages between firms' imports of intermediates and export decisions. On the one hand,
exporters with previous knowledge and experience operating in international markets may find it eas-
ier to incorporate foreign inputs in their production process. Moreover, they may feel the competitive
pressure of other traders that incorporate higher quality inputs. On the other hand, if importers of
intermediates profit from the diffusion of new technologies and knowledge embodied in the imported
inputs and produce higher quality products, this may facilitate their exports.
1 Henceforth, it should be understood that when we speak about exports, we refer to exports of the final product of the firm
(that could be an intermediate input for other firms), and, when we speak about imports of intermediates, we refer to imports
of intermediate inputs.
|
645
MÁÑEZ CASTILLEJO ET AL.
A crucial point in the analysis of the dynamic linkages between importing intermediates and ex-
porting is the recognition that both activities may imply costs that are sunk in nature. For instance,
exporters have to research foreign demand and competition, establish marketing and distribution chan-
nels, and adjust their product characteristics to meet foreign tastes and/or fulfil quality and security
legislation of other countries. Further, importers need to invest resources to find the international
suppliers that better meet their needs both in terms of costs and quality. Acknowledging the existence
of sunk costs implies that current exports and imports depend on past exports and imports trajectories,
and, more interestingly, that transitory changes in trade policy or conditions may lead to permanent
changes in trade status; that is, sunk entry or exit costs produce hysteresis in trade flows.2 Nevertheless,
it is important to note that although persistence in exporting and/or importing might be caused by sunk
costs, there might be other competing sources of persistence, such as underlying (either observed or
unobserved) firm heterogeneity.
In our analysis of the dynamic linkages between firms' imports of intermediates and export deci-
sions, we explicitly recognise the role that importing/exporting sunk costs might play. In particular,
we estimate a maximum likelihood dynamic model of the firms' joint strategy of importing interme-
diates and exporting in which we allow firms' past import (export) decisions to affect not only future
import (export) decisions but also export (import) decisions, since the performance of one activity
can enhance expected gains of the performance of the other. Furthermore, when controlling for com-
peting sources of persistence in a given trading status, we devote special attention to the role of past
productivity, as it will allow exploring possible self‐selection/continuation effects into importing of
intermediates and/or exporting (Aw, Roberts, & Xu, 2011; Máñez‐Castillejo, Rochina‐Barrachina, &
Sanchis‐Llopis, 2015).
The second strand of the international trade literature we aim to contribute is related to the link
between firms' trading activities and productivity. The relationship between exports and productivity
has been comprehensively studied.3 The empirical evidence suggests that exporters are more produc-
tive than non‐exporters (see Bernard & Jensen, 1999, among others). This could be the result of a
process of self‐selection of the more productive firms into foreign markets (Melitz, 2003) and/or may
arise from potential productivity gains that stem from export participation (learning‐by‐exporting
hypothesis, LBE henceforth). Productivity gains from exporting are usually related to growth of sales
that allows firms profiting from economies of scale, knowledge flows from foreign customers or in-
creased competition in foreign markets that forces firms to behave more efficiently. Whereas there is
widespread empirical evidence on self‐selection, the evidence on LBE is mixed and far from conclu-
sive. There are studies that do not find any evidence of LBE, and among those that do find evidence
in favour of it, the findings differ both in the magnitude and in the duration of the LBE effect.4
De Loecker (2013), however, argues that most previous tests for LBE could be flawed. The usual
empirical strategy is to look at whether a productivity estimate, typically obtained as the residual from
a production function estimation, increases after firms become exporters. Within the framework of
the control function approach to estimate productivity (Levinsohn & Petrin, 2003; Olley & Pakes,
1996), De Loecker (2013) suggests that a proper test for the LBE hypothesis requires to move from
2 The first attempt to test for the sunk cost hysteresis hypothesis in exporting is Roberts and Tybout (1997), for Colombian
manufacturing. More recent empirical evidence is Bernard and Jensen (2004) for the US, and Campa (2004) and Máñez‐
Castillejo et al. (2008) for Spain.
3 See Greenaway and Kneller (2007), Wagner (2007, 2012) and ISGEP (2008) for thorough reviews of this literature.
4 Silva et al. (2010) provide a detailed survey on the LBE literature. Further, Martins and Yang (2009) provide a meta‐analysis
for 33 empirical studies. Singh (2010) concludes that studies supporting self‐selection overwhelm studies supporting
learning‐by‐exporting.
646
|
MÁÑEZ CASTILLEJO ET AL.
the standard assumption that productivity is governed by an exogenous Markov process to assum-
ing a more general (endogenous) Markov process in which past export experience might influence
future productivity. Some recent papers following this approach are De Loecker (2007, 2013), De
Loecker and Warzynski (2012), Manjón, Máñez, Rochina‐Barrachina, and Sanchis‐Llopis (2013),
Máñez‐Castillejo, Rochina‐Barrachina, Sanchis‐Llopis, and Vicente (2014) and Máñez‐Castillejo et
al. (2015).
In recent years, there is an increasing interest in the analysis of the impact of importing intermedi-
ate inputs on productivity. Special attention has been paid to test the hypothesis of learning‐by‐import-
ing (LBI, henceforth), that is to test whether importing intermediates results in an increase in firms'
productivity. If importing firms have access to a wider variety of intermediate inputs and/or to higher
quality inputs and, therefore, may benefit from the diffusion and adoption of new technologies and
knowledge embodied in imported inputs, this can result in productivity increases. The empirical evi-
dence for the LBI hypothesis, using firm‐level data, is mixed. Van Biesebroeck (2008) using Colombian
data finds that productivity growth is correlated more strongly with firm's export status than with the
use of imported inputs; and, similarly, Muendler (2004) finds a small contribution of foreign materials
and investments goods on output for Brazil. In contrast, Kasahara and Rodrigue (2008),5 Amiti and
Konings (2007) and Halpern, Koren, and Szeidl (2015) find that importing intermediates has a posi-
tive effect on firms' productivity for Chile, Indonesia and Hungary, respectively.6
Only a few empirical studies examine simultaneously the effects of importing intermediates
and exporting on productivity at the microlevel. Among them, it is worth mentioning Kasahara and
Lapham (2013), who devise a model with heterogeneous final good producers who simultaneously
choose whether to export their output and to use imported intermediates. They estimate a structural
model with Chilean plant‐level data that confirms that there are aggregate productivity and welfare
gains due to trade in both final goods and intermediates.
We aim to contribute to this strand of the international trade literature carrying out a joint robust
test both for the LBE and LBI hypotheses. To fulfil this task, we follow De Loecker (2013) to estimate
total factor productivity (TFP henceforth). We use a procedure based in the control function approach
framework to estimate TFP, although we consider a more general law of motion of productivity as we
allow past export and import experience to affect future productivity. Then, we use this estimated TFP
as dependent variable of an equation in which we test for LBI and LBE while explicitly recognising
the existence of state dependence (persistence) on productivity.
As mentioned above, the third strand of the literature we aim to contribute is on the analysis of the
impact of firms' trading strategies on markups (defined as the ratio of price to marginal cost). Both im-
porting intermediates and exporting may have an impact on firms' markups through the marginal cost
and/or the price channel. As for the marginal cost channel for exports, if the LBE mechanism operates
(so exporting firms become more efficient) and there is not full pass through to prices of the marginal
cost reduction, the result will be an increase in markups. Furthermore, if a necessary condition to be
competitive in international markets is the production of higher quality differentiated products, this
may result in a potential reduction in the demand price elasticity of the exporters' portfolio of products
that will allow them to increase prices and enjoy higher margins (price channel). With respect to the
marginal cost channel for imports, if importing inputs allows reducing production costs and there is
not full pass through to output prices, the result will be an increase in markups. Moreover, if firms
5 Kasahara and Rodrigue (2008), when estimating total factor productivity consider an endogenous Markov process for the
law governing the evolution of productivity in which past import experience may affect future productivity.
6 There are other studies (using cross‐country data) that find that importing intermediate goods (that embody technology)
increases firm productivity, such as Coe and Helpman (1995) and Coe et al. (1997).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT