Trade, environment, and income inequality: An optimal taxation approach

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12288
Date01 August 2018
Published date01 August 2018
Received: 30 November2016 Accepted: 11 December 2017
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12288
ARTICLE
Trade, environment, and income inequality: An
optimal taxation approach
Philippe Bontems1Estelle Gozlan2
1ToulouseSchool of Economics
2INRAand AgroParisTech
PhilippeBontems, Toulouse School of Economics,
INRA,IDEI, Université Toulouse Capitole, 31000
Toulouse,France(philippe.bontems@inra.fr).
EstelleGozlan, Economie Publique,
AgroParisTech,INRA,Université Paris-
Saclay,78850 Thiverval-Grignon, France
(estelle.gozlan@inra.fr).
Weare grateful to the editor and two anonymous
reviewers,whose comments greatly improved
thepaper. We also thank the seminar partici-
pantsat the University of Queensland, at Paris
EnvironmentalEconomics Seminar, and at INRA,
Rennes.
In a small open economy, how should a government pursuing both
environmental and redistributive objectives design domestic taxes
when redistribution is costly? And how does trade liberalization
affect the economy's levels of pollution and inequalities, when taxes
are optimally and endogenously adjusted? Using a general equi-
librium model under asymmetric information with two goods, two
factors (skilled and unskilled labor), and pollution, this paper char-
acterizes the optimal mixed tax system (nonlinear income tax and
linear commodity and production taxes/subsidies) with both pro-
duction and consumption externalities. While optimal income taxes
are not directly affected by environmental externalities, conditions
are derived under which under- or over-internalization of social
marginaldamage is optimal for redistributive considerations. Assum-
ing that redistribution operates in favor of the unskilled workers
and that the dirty sector is intensive in unskilled labor, simulations
suggest that trade liberalization involves a clear trade-off between
the reduction of inequalities and the control of pollution when the
source of externality is only production; this is not necessarily true
with a consumption externality.Finally, an increase in the willingness
to redistribute income toward the unskilled results paradoxically in
less pollution and more income inequalities.
1INTRODUCTION
The social and environmental consequences of trade liberalization have receivedc onsiderableattention both in civil
society and in the economic literature. Governments in developed countries regularly face antiglobalization move-
ments, due to concerns about job losses, growing inequalities, increased pressure on the environment, and national
sovereigntylosses.1Conversely, environmental protection is often seen as a threat to international competitiveness in
political debates.
1The success of protectionist parties in the 2014 elections for the European parliament, and activism against the US-EU negotiations on the Transatlantic
FreeTrade Area, are recent illustrations of such concerns. Recently, Donald Trump'selection has been seen by many analysts as the result of political claims
resurgencefrom losers of globalization.
Journal of Public Economic Theory.2018;20:557–581. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet c
2018 Wiley Periodicals,Inc. 557
558 BONTEMS AND GOZLAN
It is sometimes argued that many negative outcomes imputed to trade liberalization are rather the consequence
of missing or badly designed environmental and redistributive policies. Among trade economists, there is wide agree-
ment that domestic distortions should be addressed through domestic policy intervention, and that trade restrictions
for domestic policy objectives can at best be second best (Bhagwati, 1994). In particular, when local environmen-
tal externalities are the only market failure, a move toward free trade with optimal environmental policy is always
welfare-improving, eventhough it may involve an increase in pollution: with endogenous policy, any increase/decrease
in pollution then reflects an optimal trade-off between pollution and income at the country level (Copeland & Taylor,
2003). However,these results are obtained within a representative–agent framework. Yet,the view that the efficiency
gains brought by trade liberalizationallow governments to leave everyone better off with well-targeted redistributive
policies has been objected in modern normative economic theory: because individual characteristics are not directly
observable by governments, individualized lump-sum transfersare not feasible in practice, which challenges the sepa-
ration of efficiency and redistributiveconsiderations (Guesnerie, 2001; Naito, 1996; Tuomala, 2016).
On the other hand, environmental policyitself c anhave important distributive effects across heterogeneous house-
holds, whether it be through the regressive effect of consumption taxes (if low-income individuals are affected more
heavily), or be it through changes in relative returns to factors resulting from production taxes.2In other words,
the internalization of both consumption and production externalities might interfere with any given redistribution
objective.
Keeping this in mind calls for a fresh look at the optimal tax system as a whole in an open economy (i.e., where the
pattern of specialization matters for environmental and inequality-related outcomes), when the government pursues
both environmental and redistributive objectives. In particular,one would like to know under which conditions reduc-
ing pollution and redistributing wealth are conflicting tasks if any. Also, one would liketo know how the government
should adapt its fiscal system including environmental taxes when facing exogenousshocks like increasing globaliza-
tion or changes in social preferences with respect to wealth redistribution.
To address these issues, we consider a Heckscher–Ohlin model of a small open economywith two sectors (clean
and polluting) and two factors (skilled and unskilled labor). Assuming that emissions may arise either from the produc-
tion or from the consumption of the polluting good, we characterize the optimal tax system when policy is constrained
only by the information available to the regulator.The government maximizes a weighted sum of skilled and unskilled
agents'utility,using nonlinear income taxes (because skills are not observable) and linear taxes/subsidies on consump-
tion and production of the polluting good (because purchases are anonymous). Income redistribution is socially costly
because of incentive compatibility. While optimal income taxesare not directly affected by environmental externali-
ties, we show that optimal distortion of the consumer and the producer prices in the polluting sector consist in a Pigo-
vian term and a redistributive term. It is then optimal to over- or underinternalize the social marginal environmental
damage whenever it helps decreasing the cost of wealth redistribution due to incentive compatibility. FromPirttilä
and Tuomala (1997), we know that, for consumption externalities, this depends on the way pollution, consumption,
and leisure interact within individual preferences. In the present paper,because the nonlinear technology with imper-
fect substitutability between skilled and unskilled labor types makes wages endogenous, it is also optimal to distort
producer prices for redistributiveconsiderations; if the sector making intensive use of unskilled labor is also character-
ized by production externalities,then the Pigovian and redistributive components of the production tax/subsidy are of
opposite signs (underinternalization).
We then explore the consequences on the level of pollution and inequality of exogenousshocks on this economy,
when taxes are optimally and endogenously adjusted. We show that (i) under openness to trade, the source of the
externality (consumption or production) matters for redistribution, while it is not the case in autarky; (ii) whether the
economyspecializes into the clean or the dirty sector, trade liberalization involvesa clear trade-off between the control
of income inequalities and the control of pollution when the source of externality is production; this is not necessarily
true with a consumption externality; (iii) an increasing willingness to redistribute income corresponds to a shrinking
2SeeFullerton (2011) for a complete review of the mechanisms at stake, including the possibility that different types of agents might face different damages
fromemissions (a possibility not considered in this paper).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT