Top-Down Accountability, Social Unrest, and Anticorruption in China

AuthorLinke Hou,Mingxing Liu,Dong Zhang
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/02750740221100522
Published date01 August 2022
Date01 August 2022
Subject MatterArticles
Top-Down Accountability, Social Unrest,
and Anticorruption in China
Linke Hou
1
, Mingxing Liu
2
and Dong Zhang
3
Abstract
What motivates front-line ofcials to curtail corruption? We contend that performance management can reinforce top-down
accountability in authoritarian governments and help contain corruption at the local level. Drawing on a nationally represen-
tative panel data of approximately 120 villages in China, we nd that when anticorruption is prescribed as a salient policy goal
in the township-to-village performance evaluation, village ofcials are incentivized to curb corruption. We further present
evidence that the mandate for maintaining social stability propels township-level governments to prioritize the anticorruption
work in the performance evaluation of village ofcials given that corruption constitutes a crucial trigger for social unrest. Our
study sheds light on the understanding of performance management, bureaucratic accountability, and anticorruption policies in
authoritarian countries.
Keywords
Performance management, anticorruption, social unrest, China
Introduction
Endemic corruption not only plagues the public sector (e.g.,
Anderson & Tverdova, 2003; Liu & Mikesell, 2014, 2019;
Liu et al., 2017, 2021; Rose-Ackerman, 1999), but also has
pernicious economic and social repercussions (e.g., Mauro,
1995; Villoria et al., 2013; Zhang & Kim, 2018; Zhu et al.,
2019). Desiring clean governments and good governance,
policy makers, academics, and the general public are all
searching for effective policies to combat corruption (for a
review, see Gans-Morse et al., 2018).
A growing body of literature highlights the effectiveness
of top-down anticorruption policiesincluding monitoring,
audits, and investigationinitiated by higher authorities
(e.g., Avis et al., 2018; Bobonis et al., 2016; Ni & Su,
2019; Olken, 2007; Serra, 2012). Bottom-up anticorruption
approaches, with an emphasis on civil society monitoring
and citizen-led whistle-blowing, have also attracted increas-
ing attention from scholars, although there is mixed evidence
to establish the effectiveness of these approaches (e.g., Bashir
et al., 2011; Gong, 2000; Lavena, 2016; Olken, 2007; Serra,
2012; Su, 2020; Su & Ni, 2018).
Despite the improved understanding of anticorruption
strategies based on growing empirical evidence, anticorrup-
tion reforms have made very limited progress in the real
world (Jancsics, 2019). Fundamentally, political leaders
and government ofcials often lack incentives to combat cor-
ruption, especially in developing countries. For instance, the
scale-up of a promising anticorruption program in India had
to be shelved because it threatened the rents of local ofcials
and propelled them to lobby the state government for its can-
celation (Banerjee et al., 2017). While the existing scholar-
ship on anticorruption has devoted a great deal of attention
to the effectiveness of anticorruption policies, the anticorrup-
tion incentives of government ofcials are relatively under-
studied. What motivates local government ofcials to ght
corruption? If top-down monitoring is truly effective in
curbing corruption, under what circumstances do govern-
ment ofcials impose top-down anticorruption approach?
In this study, we attempt to answer these questions in the
context of China. China constitutes an intriguing case for
studying corruption and anticorruption in the sense that
rampant corruption puzzlingly coexists alongside a stellar
record in economic performance during the post-1978
reform era. One plausible account of this puzzle is that the
Chinese governments anticorruption endeavors have to
some extent prevented corruption from spiraling out of
control, albeit failing to systematically reduce corruption
(Wedeman, 2012). Another explanation is that centralized
1
Center for Economic Research, Shandong University, Jinan, China
2
China Institute for Educational Finance Research, Peking University, Beijing,
China
3
Division of Social Science, The Hong Kong University of Science and
Technology, Clear Water Bay, Hong Kong
Corresponding Author:
Dong Zhang, Division of Social Science, The Hong Kong University of
Science and Technology, Rm. 2381, Academic Building, Clear Water Bay,
Hong Kong.
Email: dongzhang@ust.hk
Article
American Review of Public Administration
2022, Vol. 52(6) 423438
© The Author(s) 2022
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/02750740221100522
journals.sagepub.com/home/arp
and decentralized corruption have different implications for
governance (Shleifer & Vishny, 1993). Like other East
Asian countries, corruption is relatively centralized in
China, such that the pettycorruption of local government
ofcials and street-level bureaucrats has been largely con-
tained (Bardhan, 1997). In view of these insights, unraveling
the logic of anticorruption at the local level in China is crucial
for understanding both how the Chinese governments anti-
corruption initiatives translate into front-line bureaucrats
efforts on the ground through a fairly centralized political
system, and how the local bureaucracy actually works to
curtail pettycorruption.
We contend that the Chinese governments performance
management system imposes top-down accountability upon
local government ofcials and offers incentives for monitor-
ing and combating corruption at the local level. Performance
management serves as a critical tool for higher-level ofcials
to control local state agents and ensure local policy compli-
ance (e.g., Edin, 2003; Gao, 2009). In a multitasking environ-
ment of bureaucracy (Dixit, 2002; Holmstrom & Milgrom,
1991), lower-level ofcials are motivated to carry out poli-
cies prioritized by higher-level authorities. When anticorrup-
tion becomes a primary policy target demanded by
higher-level ofcials in performance evaluation schemes,
lower-level ofcials tend to take measures to curb corruption
to demonstrate their compliance with policies emanating
from higher-level authorities.
Local governance entities in China consist of provincial,
municipal, county, township, and village levels of adminis-
tration. In this study, we leverage three waves of a nationally
representative survey of approximately 120 villages to
explore the determinants of anticorruption incentives at the
village and township levels in China. This survey, adminis-
tered by the China Center for Agricultural Policy of the
Chinese Academy of Sciences, yields one of the few compre-
hensive data sets on the performance evaluation of Chinese
local ofcials at the county, township, and village levels
(e.g., Hou et al., 2018; Lu & Tao, 2017). According to this
survey, performance targets, including general targets and
veto targets, are widely used in county-to-township and
township-to-village evaluation schemes. For general
targets, political leaders from township to village levels
were asked to list their ve most important policy targets
imposed in the performance evaluation system; for veto
targets, political leaders were asked to list the policy targets
that would nullify all other performance achievements if
they were not fullled. Using xed-effects models, we docu-
ment that when anticorruption was included both as one of
the top-ve general targets and as a veto target in
township-to-village evaluation schemes, village leaders
were more likely to take measures to curtail corruption to
fulll political mandates from the township-level leadership.
In enforcing top-down monitoring, however, township
government ofcials do not act out of benevolence. The
reason why they decide to set anticorruption as a priority
lies in their concern for maintaining social stability. We
present evidence that corruption has been a crucial trigger
of social unrest in local China. When county-level ofcials
are concerned about social unrest, and thus set maintaining
social stability as a primary policy goal, township-level of-
cials tend to prioritize anticorruption work to prevent mass
collective actions.
Our research makes several contributions to the existing
scholarship. First, departing from recent evidence-based
research that has documented the effectiveness of top-down
monitoring in curbing corruption (Avis et al., 2018;
Bobonis et al., 2016; Ni & Su, 2019; Olken, 2007; Serra,
2012), we shift attention to the incentives for ghting corrup-
tion and enforcing top-down monitoring strategies in local
governments. Second, to the extent that some scholars
emphasize the importance of top leaderships political will
in combating corruption (e.g., Choi, 2009; Quah, 1994), we
advance this line of research by studying how anticorruption
initiatives at higher levels of governments translate into front-
line ofcialsefforts on the ground, and exploring what
drives anticorruption initiatives in the rst place. Third,
while one strand of the literature devotes its attention to
bureaucratsintrinsic and extrinsic motivations to engage in
or refrain from corruption individually (e.g., Kwon, 2014;
Perry, 1996; Zhang et al., 2019), we focus on the motivations
to implement anticorruption policies and practices. Finally,
our study enriches the literature on the effectiveness of per-
formance management (Gerrish, 2016) by showing that
even in an authoritarian state, top-down accountability pro-
vided by the performance management system can help
curb corruption at the local level to some extent.
Top-Down Accountability and Performance
Management
In the absence of free, fair, and competitiveelections, political
leaders in authoritarian states are not accountable to citizens.
Despite the absence of bottom-up accountability, we empha-
size how top-down accountability can discipline lower-level
ofcialsbehaviors and prompt them to be accountable to
higher-level ofcials. Our conceptualization of top-down
accountability resonates with the denition of bureaucratic
accountabilityoutlined in Romzek & Dubnicks (1987,
p. 228) classical framework: the expectations of public
administrators are managed through focusing attention on
the priorities of those at the top of the bureaucratic hierarchy.
In the public sector, performance management plays a crit-
ical role in enhancing top-down accountability. Performance
management emerged in the public sector in the 1970s
(Moynihan, 2008) and ourished with the advent of New
Public Management, the principal doctrines of which
include explicit standards and measures of performance as
well as output controls (Hood, 1991). One major objective
of performance management is to improve the 3Es”—
424 American Review of Public Administration 52(6)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT