Thresholds of financial development in the Euro area

AuthorMunusamy Dharani,Vighneswara Swamy
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12902
Date01 June 2020
Published date01 June 2020
1730
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/twec World Econ. 2020;43:1730–1774.
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Received: 22 October 2018
|
Revised: 9 October 2019
|
Accepted: 12 November 2019
DOI: 10.1111/twec.12902
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Thresholds of financial development in the Euro
area
VighneswaraSwamy1
|
MunusamyDharani2
1Department of Economics, ICFAI Business School (IBS) (A Constituent of IFHE, Deemed to be University), Hyderabad,
India
2Department of Finance, ICFAI Business School (IBS) (A Constituent of IFHE, Deemed to be University), Hyderabad, India
KEYWORDS
dynamic panel threshold, economic growth, financial development, non-monotonicity
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Does the inordinately high level of finance cause a decline in economic growth? Does the positive
effect of finance on economic growth vanish as the financial thresholds are surpassed? Is there an
"optimal" level of financial development that is more vital in accelerating growth? These have been
the more often asked important questions in the finance–growth nexus debate.
As the financial development indicators in Euro area countries are growing at astonishingly high
levels, there is a need being felt among the researchers and policymakers to understand the effects of
the upsurge of financial development on economic growth. The macroeconomic data reveal that while
the domestic credit in Spain has more than doubled from 74% to 171% of GDP over the last three
decades, economic growth has gone into a negative trajectory from 1.77% to −1.23%. The domestic
credit in Portugal has more than doubled from 73% to 169% of GDP, while the economic growth has
plummeted from −0.17% to −1.36%. Similarly, domestic credit grew from 47% to 117% of GDP in
Italy, and the economic growth slumped from 1.17% to −1.93%. Chong, Mody, and Sandoval (2017)
observe that a negative association between bank credit and economic growth has emerged stronger
after 1990 and was exceptionally prominent in the Eurozone, consistent with the view that an over-
grown financial sector wanes economic growth potential. This leads us to ask: Is there a non-mono-
tonic relationship between higher financial development and economic growth as growing finance is
linked with less growth? However, we do not find a comprehensive study that explores the finance–
growth nexus in the Euro area. Therefore, this paper investigates the presence of thresholds in Euro
area countries beyond which the financial development changes in magnitude.
The global financial crisis has, indeed, necessitated a re-examination of the role and benefits of
financial development, predominantly from the perspective of the upsurge of complex financial in-
struments. The sophisticated contemporary finance has intensified the gravity and frequency of crises
while producing not enough gains to the broader economy. Financial innovation and liberalisation,
in this notion, has in fact favoured a few substantially but hurt many. In this context, Rodrik (2008)
|
1731
SWAMY And dHARAnI
asks: Is there evidence of the benefits of financial innovation in the societal perspective in making our
lives measurably and unambiguously better off? In a similar critical viewpoint, Wolf (2009) observes
that something is wrong with a condition in which, "instead of being a servant, finance had become
the economy's master." This, indeed, has triggered the revival of the debate on the appropriate levels
of financial development and the approach towards financial development for achieving sustainable
economic growth.
One strand of the finance–economic growth literature maintains finance is an engine of
growth (Bencivenga & Smith, 1991; Gurley & Shaw, 1955; King & Levine, 1993; Levine, 2005;
Levine, Loayza, & Beck, 2000; McKinnon, 1973; Schumpeter & Opie, 1934). Although finan-
cial development has a major role in furthering economic development, sceptics suspect the
finance–growth nexus hypothesis at higher levels of financial development and dispute that the
role of financial development is overstated (Lucas, 1988; Panizza, 2012; Robinson, 1952; Rodrik
& Subramanian, 2009). This thread of the literature claims that economic growth steers the need
for financial services instead of the other way around. Deidda (2006) argues that as the economy
reaches a certain level of economic development, financial development occurs endogenously.
In a controversial paper, at that time, Rajan (2005) emphasised the hazards of financial develop-
ment, as the presence of an enormous and complicated financial system enhances the likelihood
of a "catastrophic meltdown." Gennaioli, Shleifer, and Vishny (2010) claim that in the presence
of some overlooked tail risk, financial innovation can trigger off financial fragility, even in the
absence of leverage.
Apropos of the ongoing finance–growth nexus debate, from an empirical perspective, this paper
makes three contributions to the finance–growth literature: first, we focus especially on the Euro area
economies in view of their significantly higher levels of financial development. Second, in exploring
the finance–growth nexus, there is a need to focus on the developed countries with very high levels of
financial development, as averaging across developing countries alone would make inferences intri-
cate. Third, we allow for a very flexible approach to account for unobserved heterogeneity (and thus
endogeneity) in our model, which could arise from the omitted variables and/or global shocks whose
impact differs across the countries. Furthermore, this study seeks to know the following: (a) Is there a
threshold for financial development in the Euro area? (b) Is the relationship between financial devel-
opment and economic growth weak in financial development levels below the threshold? (c) Is there
a waning negative relationship between financial development and growth as the threshold levels are
crossed? (d) How critical would the impact of financial development on growth be beyond its thresh-
old? This study offers a new discrete empirical evidence based on an exclusive Euro area country data
set, well beyond the selective anecdotal evidence. The results have potentially important implications
for financial regulation.
This study overcomes the issues related to data adequacy, exclusive coverage of countries, hetero-
geneity, endogeneity and non-linearities. We analyse the finance–growth relationship within a stan-
dard neoclassical growth framework. Empirical research, of late, has focused on the possibility of
non-linearities within the finance–growth relationship, with explicit attention to high financial devel-
opment levels. The empirical literature on this topic remains sparse as very few studies use non-linear
impact analysis (Deidda & Fattouh, 2002). We provide an in-depth econometric analysis that allows
for non-linear estimation between financial development and economic growth in order to investigate
the possibility of the economy being adversely affected due to "too much" finance.
The remainder of the paper is organised as follows: Section 2 reviews the literature on financial
development–economic growth relationship. Section 3 details the data set. Section 4 describes our
estimation strategy. Section 5 provides a detailed discussion of the results. Finally, Section 6 is the
conclusion.
1732
|
SWAMY And dHARAnI
2
|
REVIEW OF LITERATURE
One strand of financial development literature observes that finance stimulates rapid, long-run growth.
Greenwood and Jovanovic (1990) observe the presence of a two-way relationship as the financial in-
termediaries stimulate investment and growth drives the growth of financial development. Examining
the endogenous emergence of a financial sector at a certain critical level of economic development by
assuming a fixed cost of financial transactions, Saint-Paul (1992), Zilibotti (1994) and Blackburn and
Hung (1998) conclude that financial development is predominantly growth-enhancing. Some studies
emphasise the bank credit channel of financial development and show that financial development can
boost or deteriorate economic growth based on the types of bank credit (Aghion, Angeletos, Banerjee,
& Manova, 2010; Beck, Buyukkaraback, Rioja, & Valev, 2012; Beck, Degryse, & Kneer, 2012; Sassi
& Gasmi, 2014). The positive effect of financial development on economic growth is mostly powered
by enterprise credit rather than consumer credit (Beck, Buyukkaraback, et al., 2012; Beck, Degryse, et
al., 2012). However, some studies question the robustness of the finance–growth nexus. Demetriades
and Hussein (1996) claim that they did not find substantiation of a causal relationship moving from
finance to growth in their study comprising 16 countries. Demetriades and Law (2006), while un-
derscoring the role of institutional factors, demonstrate that financial depth does not cause growth
in countries with inefficient institutions. Emphasising the inflation channel, Rousseau and Wachtel
(2002) notice that growing finance does not contribute to economic growth in countries with double-
digit inflation. Further, Rousseau and Wachtel (2011) also notice a waning effect of financial depth
and indicate that credit to the private sector has no statistically significant impact on GDP growth. The
general critique of the research based on cross-sectional data using standard OLS estimation meth-
ods which envisaged the finance–growth nexus is that conclusions based on cross-sectional analysis
are unreliable and have numerous econometric problems (Barro, 1991; Beck, Buyukkaraback, et al.,
2012; Christopoulos & Tsionas, 2004).
Another thread of literature stems from the perspective that the large financial system is just a
by-product of the overall process of economic development and is well symbolised by the assertion
that "where enterprise leads, finance follows" (Robinson, 1952). Some researchers, since the 1990s,
have claimed that there exists a causal link going from finance to growth. King and Levine (1993)
highlighted financial depth as a predictor of economic growth. Further, evidence in this direction
evolved from Levine and Zervos (1998) who demonstrated that stock market liquidity is a predictor of
economic growth. Likewise, Levine et al. (2000) used different types of instruments and economet-
ric techniques to notice the presence of a causal relationship running from finance to growth. In this
direction, the much-cited evidence came from Rajan and Zingales (1998) as they demonstrated the
causal link going from financial to economic growth through the industrial sectors.
The second feature of this study is the issue of non-linearity in the finance–growth nexus. In
the models (e.g., Acemoglu & Zilibotti, 1997; Greenwood & Jovanovic, 1990) where endogenously
emerging financial institutions usually have a positive effect on growth, the magnitude varies with
the level of economic development. These present a non-linear relationship between financial and
economic development. Interestingly, very few studies have explored the non-monotonic relation-
ship between financial and economic development (Aghion, Howitt, & Mayer-Foulkes, 2005; Deidda
& Fattouh, 2002; Easterly, Islam, & Stiglitz, 2000; Rioja & Valev, 2004; Shen & Lee, 2006) and
illustrate that there is a convex and non-monotonic relationship between financial depth and the vol-
atility of output growth. Some of the recent studies establish a non-linear relationship between fi-
nance and growth in which higher financial development may strengthen economic growth before a
certain threshold of financial development is reached (Arcand, Berkes, & Panizza, 2012; Cecchetti
& Kharroubi, 2012; Samargandi, Fidrmuc, & Ghosh, 2015). Likewise, Law and Singh (2014) use a

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT