Three Worlds of Working Time: The Partisan and Welfare Politics of Work Hours in Industrialized Countries

DOI10.1177/0032329204269983
Date01 December 2004
Published date01 December 2004
AuthorBrian Burgoon,Phineas Baxandall
Subject MatterArticles
10.1177/0032329204269983ARTICLEPOLITICS & SOCIETYBRIAN BURGOON and PHINEAS BAXANDALL
Three Worlds of Working Time:
The Partisan and Welfare Politics of
Work Hours in Industrialized Countries
BRIAN BURGOON
PHINEAS BAXANDALL
This article argues that annual hours per employed person and per working-age
person capture important dimensions of political-economic success that should
be weighed against aggregateemployment and wealth patterns. It also argues that
partisan-driven work-time policies and welfare-regime institutions give rise to
diverging Social Democratic, Liberal,and Christian Democratic “worlds” of work
time in terms of these two measures.Descriptive statistics for eighteen Organization
for Economic Cooperation and Development countries revealbroad clustering and
trendssuggestive of the Three Worlds,while panel estimation suggests the influence
of partisan and welfare-institutional conditions underlying them. Case study of Fin-
land, the United States, and the Netherlands further illustrates the political process
and sequence of the Three Worlds.
Keywords: working hours; time; welfare state; social policy; partisan; Christian
Democracy; Social Democracy
How much people work is an important and contested part of economic life.
Howeverit is measured, the number of hours on the job captures how much time a
person spends on earning instead of on other pursuits. By some normative stan-
dards, working fewer hours is an important measure of the “good life,” to be
Wewish to particularly thank the following colleaguesfor their useful critiques and suggestions:
Mark Blyth, Fred Block, Archon Fung, Colin Hay,Anton Hemerijck, Wade Jacoby,Gerd Junne, Jac-
queline O’Reilly,Martin Rein, Robert van der Veen, Robin Varghese,and seminar participants at the
Universityof Amsterdam, Council for European Studies, andAmerican Political Science Association.
BrianBurgoon also wishes to thank the Amsterdam School for Social Research for financial support.
POLITICS & SOCIETY, Vol. 32 No. 4, December 2004 439-473
DOI: 10.1177/0032329204269983
© 2004 Sage Publications
439
weighed against growth, employment, and other measures of economic well-
being. Higher number of hours worked by Americans than their European or even
Japanese counterparts has raised concern about “overwork” that blemishes the
United States’ employment and growth success, while the long vacations and
early retirement of many European economies has raised concern about sustain-
ing economic growth and competitiveness.1Whether we lament the “overworked
American” or his “lazy-European” counterpart, working time matters to our
commonsense judgments of political-economic success. It is also the subject of
political fights between employers, unions, political parties, and others, most
directly over regulation of workdays and weeks, holidays, overtime,and the like.
France’shours-reductions to fightunemployment in the 1990s, and more recently
the German union I. G. Metall’s failed bid to extend the thirty-five-hourworking
week to East Germany all show that these fights can be front-page news.
Yetwe know surprisingly little about the politics of work time. The compara-
tive politics literature with much to say about political-economic differences
between industrialized countries has directed little attention to working time. The
study of working time, meanwhile, tells us plenty about work-time patterns, the
efficacy of work-time regulations, and industrial relations that shape both. But
it tells us much less about the work-time consequences of policies less directly
regulating such hours, such as social-welfare policies, or about howpartisan poli-
tics that often cut across simple Left-Right division shape national work-time
patterns.
This article’sambition is, thus, to bring more politics into the study of working
time, and more work time into the study of politics. It focuses on aggregate work
patterns capturing how much different polities work, and considers how broad
policy and social policyinstitutions might underlie these patterns. The main claim
is that the partisan-institutional differences underlying distinct Social Demo-
cratic, Liberal, and Christian Democratic “worlds of welfare capitalism”2also
generate discernable worlds of working time. Right (neoliberal) parties champion
market-led, minimalist welfare states, and they side with employers against work-
time limits, encouraging long work hours. Social Democratic parties champion
“solidaristic” welfare and work-time policies encouraging fewer work hours, but
also higher, more uniform, and equitable employment levels that limit aggregate
reductions in hours. Finally, Christian Democratic parties and their conservative-
welfare legacies have fostered male-breadwinner work and widespread labor-
market exclusion, while recent reforms of such regimes of “welfare without
work” combine part-time female employment, work sharing, and resistance to
the “twenty-four-hour economy” to produce the Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development’s (OECDs) lowest work hours.
This portrait of three worlds of work time finds empirical support in both quan-
titativeand qualitativeoverviews of work-time experience in industrialized coun-
tries. Using improved data on work hours in eighteen OECD countries, descrip-
tive statistics reveal broad clustering and trends suggestive of the Three Worlds,
440 POLITICS & SOCIETY
while time-series cross-section analysis suggests the independent influence of
partisan and welfare-institutional conditions underlying those worlds. Finally,
brief case studies from each regime type—Finland, the United States, and the
Netherlands—identify the process and sequence of work-time politics, further
supporting the argument.
1. UNDERSTUDIED POLITICS IN THE STUDY OF WORK TIME
Study of working time has been the province of labor economists and
industrial-relations specialists studying work time as part of worker life chances
and to measure economic productivity. A big task has been to measure basic
work-time differences over time and space.Despite significant problems in com-
paring national work time, a range of measures show that hours per employee and
per person in most industrialized countries have declined steadily since the
1870s.3Such trends reflect productivity gains associated with industrialization,
hence the generally longer hours in the undeveloped world.
Of particular interest in the work-time literature are the growing differences in
working time among industrialized countries since the 1960s, a snapshot of which
can be found in Figure 1. As this figure suggests, some OECD countries have
experienced substantial swings in the annual hours per employed person, as the
Swedish trend suggests, while the more general pattern in recent decades has been
BRIAN BURGOON and PHINEAS BAXANDALL 441
1200
1300
1400
1500
1600
1700
1800
1900
2000
2100
2200
1960 1973 1980 1990 2000
Annual Hours per Employed Person .
Japan
U.S.
OECD
Germany
Netherlands
Sweden
Figure 1. Annual hours per employed person in selected OECD countries, 1960-2000.
Source:Groningen 2003; OECD various. Total Economy Database (Groningen, the Netherlands: Uni-
versity of Groningen and the Conference Board, 2002), http://www.eco.rug.nl/ggdc.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT