THE VALUE IN FUNDAMENTAL ACCOUNTING INFORMATION

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12119
Published date01 March 2017
Date01 March 2017
THE VALUE IN FUNDAMENTAL ACCOUNTING INFORMATION
H. J. Turtle
Colorado State University
Kainan Wang
University of Toledo
Abstract
We examine the role of fundamental accounting information in shaping portfolio
performance. Using a conditional performance approach, we address the concern that
the positive relation between PiotroskisF Score and ex post returns is due to risk
compensation. Our results show that portfolios of rms with strong fundamental
underpinnings generate signicant positive and time-varying performance. One
potential source of these performance gains is an underreaction to public information
(such as momentum and F Score) when information uncertainty (proxied by size,
illiquidity, and idiosyncratic volatility) is high. In addition, conditional performance
benets seem prevalent in periods of high investor sentiment.
JEL Classification: G11, G12, G14, M41
I. Introduction
There is extensive and long-standing support for the use of fundamental valuation tools
in equity choice from the early seminal work of Graham and Dodd (1934) to the current
investment philosophy of their modern adherent Warren Buffett.
1
In addition, numerous
authors document the potential economic benets of fundamental analysis through
the judicious use of available nancial accounting information (cf. Ou and Penman 1989;
Lev and Thiagarajan 1993; Haugen and Baker 1996; Asness 1997; Frankel and Lee 1998;
Grifn and Lemmon 2002; Piotroski 2000; Mohanram 2005; Piotroski and So
2012; Novy-Marx 2013).
In recent years, the F Score, a comprehensive measure of rm fundamentals, has
drawn attention from academics and practitioners. Introduced by Piotroski (2000), the
F Score is constructed from nine accounting signals capturing three aspects of a rms
nancial strength: protability, liquidity, and operating efciency. Piotroski nds that
The authors are grateful for the helpful comments and suggestions of the editors, associate editor, referee, and
seminar participants at the 2010 Northern Finance Association meetings and the 2012 Financial Management
Association meetings.
1
For example, in his 2008 Letter to Shareholders, Buffett quips, Price is what you pay. Value is what you
get.In the Foreword to the First Edition in The Warren Buffett Way (Hagstrom 1994), Peter Lynch describes
Buffetts thought process regarding company valuation as the critical investment factor is determining the
intrinsic value of a business and paying a fair or bargain price(p. xxi).
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XL, No. 1 Pages 113140 Spring 2017
113
© 2017 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
RAWLS COLLEGE OF BUSINESS, TEXAS TECH UNIVERSITY
PUBLISHED FOR THE SOUTHERN AND SOUTHWESTERN
FINANCE ASSOCIATIONS BY WILEY-BLACKWELL PUBLISHING
the F Score has strong predictive power for ex post returns. Piotroski and So (2012)
further show that the predictability of the F Score for ex post returns is stronger when
there is substantial disagreement, or incongruence, between a rms fundamental value
(proxied by the F Score) and market-perceived value (measured by book-to-market).
Walksh
ausl (2016) further examines the returns to these incongruent portfolios with
strong F Scores and large book-to-market ratios. He nds strong unconditional portfolio
performance is also present in international markets, and there is some further indirect
evidence that the observed predictability is at least partially related to a nancing-based
mispricing factor.
Although the literature nds a strong relation between F Score and ex post
returns, the economic rationale for this relation has been debated by multiple authors. In
particular, although portfolios of high F Score stocks often produce large ex post returns,
it is not clear if these returns simply represent appropriate compensation for risk
premiums. Fama and French (2006) present a valuation framework to jointly test the
relations among expected protability, expected investment, book-to-market ratio, and
expected returns.
2
They conclude that the sources of predictability in expected returns
due to F Score could be both rational (i.e., high F Score stocks are more risky) and
irrational (i.e., high F Score stocks are more prone to mispricing). Similarly, in a recent
survey on accounting anomalies, Richardson, Tuna, and Wysocki (2010) point out that
researchers examining the relation between accounting attributes and ex post returns
must ensure that plausible risk-based explanations are precluded as alternative
explanations.
The extant literature on risk-based pricing is primarily cast in the context of an
unconditional asset pricing model in which required asset returns do not vary with
changes in the underlying information set. Recent advances in conditional performance
evaluation have the ability to assess the impact of information on marginal performance
to directly address the risk premium counterargument. For example, Ferson and Schadt
(1996) and Christopherson, Ferson, and Glassman (1998) propose conditional alpha
measures based on an underlying time-varying beta model. Jha, Korkie, and Turtle (2009)
extend this work to provide a conditional alpha that is consistent with an underlying
conditional meanvariance decision framework. The resultant conditional alpha has
desirable properties and may be readily obtained from a simple unconditional regression.
We adopt this framework to examine the importance of fundamental accounting
information in conditional performance.
The conditional alpha measures the risk-adjusted return contribution from a
conditional model of equilibrium returns. For a given equilibrium model (with
2
Through an extension of the basic valuation equation for future expected dividends, and with the addition of
a clean surplus accounting condition from Ohlson (1995), they obtain,
Pt¼X1
t¼1
E EPStþtdBtþt
ðÞ
1þrðÞ
t,
where P
t
is the stock price per share at time t,B
t
is the book value per share at time t,EPStþtis the earnings per share
at time tþt,dBtþt¼BtþtBtþt1is the similarly indexed change in book value per share, EðÞisthe expectation
operator, and ris the internal rate of return on expected dividends (cf. Fama and French 2006, p. 492). Dividing both
sides of the equation by the book value of equity produces the results discussed.
114 The Journal of Financial Research

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT