The valuation effects of unit versus share‐only IPOs

Published date01 October 2021
AuthorMengxi Chen
Date01 October 2021
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/jcaf.22511
Received: 25 May 2021Accepted: 7 July 2021
DOI: 10.1002/jcaf.22511
RESEARCH ARTICLE
The valuation effects of unit versus share-only IPOs
Mengxi Chen
Department of Finance, Central
Connecticut State University, New
Britain, Connecticut, USA
Correspondence
MengxiChen, Department of Finance,
CentralConnecticut State University, 1615
StanleySt, New Britain, CT 06050, USA.
Email:mengxi.chen@ccsu.edu
Iwould like to thank Jack Cooney for his
invaluablehelp and comments and semi-
narparticipants at Texas TechUniversity
andCentral Connecticut State University.
Anyremaining errors are my own.
Abstract
Units consist of shares and warrants. Some firms issue units in initial public
offerings (IPOs) after which warrant holders can exercise warrantsand purchase
shares from the issuer.Why do firms choose to issue units instead of only shares?
I answer this question based on Merton’sinvestor recognition model. Firms lack-
ing pre-IPO publicity can benefit from an increase in investor recognition. I
find that unit firms have less pre-IPO publicity than share-only firms. Separate
trading between warrants and shares and eventual exercise of the warrants will
increase the number of shareholders and therefore firm value.
KEYWORDS
firm value, initial public offerings, investor recognition, unit offerings, warrants
JEL CLASSIFICATION
G24, G32
1 INTRODUCTION
A unit offering is an offering composed of a combination
of common shares and long-term warrants to purchase
common shares. From 1996 to 2016, 8.4% of initial public
offerings (IPOs) in my sample were classified as units.
However, despite their prevalence, few academic studies
examine unit offerings and most specifically exclude unit
offerings from their sample.1A representative example of a
unit IPO offering was made by Xybernaut Corporation on
July 18, 1996. There were 2.1 million units offered at a price
of $5.50 per unit. Each unit was composed of one share of
common stock and one warrant. Each warrant authorized
its holder to purchase one share of Xybernaut Corporation
common stock at $9, starting from the issue day until July
17, 1999 (i.e., 3 yearsafter the issue date). Starting 18 months
after the offering, the company was allowed to redeem the
warrants at a price of $0.05 if the common stock closing
price was equal to or higher than $18 for 20 consecutive
trading days. The units, common stock, and warrants in
this offering were listed on NASDAQ and investors could
separately trade each of these three securities (the shares,
the warrants, and the units) immediately after the offering.
Studies exclude unit offerings from analyses probably
because adding warrants makes unit offerings fundamen-
tally different from share-only offerings. However,as men-
tioned earlier,unit offerings are not a minor part of the IPO
market. My main research question centers on why firms
choose to issue warrants along with common stock. Prac-
titioners believe that warrants function as “sweeteners” in
the offerings to induce investors to buy shares of firms
that receive little attention from the public (e.g., Business
Week [May 13, 1991]). Academics, on the other hand, have
focused on two theories for the use of unit offerings: the
“agency cost” theory proposed by Schultz (1993) and the
asymmetric information theory offered by Chemmanur
and Fulghieri (1997). According to Schultz’s (1993)agency
cost theory, unit offerings solve the free cash flow agency
problem in IPOs through the use of staged financing. Rais-
ing all the cash necessary to finance a new project at the
IPO stage leads to managers possibly squandering money
if the project turns out to have a negative net present value
(NPV). Warrants are therefore used to raise the additional
funds only if the project is proven valuable, as evidenced
by an increase in stock price. On the other hand, the infor-
mation asymmetry theory proposed by Chemmanur and
J Corp Account Finance. 2021;32:7–26. © 2021 Wiley Periodicals LLC7wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jcaf
8CHEN
Fulghieri (1997) argues that insiders with private informa-
tion use the portion of firm value sold as warrants as a
signal of firm quality. In an equity market characterized
by information asymmetry and to maximize the expected
utility of firm insiders, firms having high expected cash
flows and high riskiness would cut back on retained equity
ownership and underpricing by increasing the portion of
firm value sold as warrants. This happens especially when
they find that employing the signal of retaining equity and
underpricing becomes relatively more expensive as firm
riskiness increases. However, it is costly for firms having
low expected cash flows to mimic this signaling package.
In a separating equilibrium, the most effective signaling
strategy turns out to involveretaining equity, underpricing,
and adding warrants. Therefore, according to Chemmanur
and Fulghieri (1997), only firms that have high expected
cash flows and very high risk issue units while low-risk
firms issue equity alone.
Several studies have tested these two theories. Some
findings are supportive of one theory but not the other
(How & Howe, 2001; Lee et al. 2003) and some cannot
be fully explained by these two theories (Byoun, 2004). In
this paper, I offer a third explanation for whyissuing firms
utilize the unit offer method based on the investor recog-
nition hypothesis in Merton (1987). Merton assumes that
when investorsconstruct their portfolios, they would select
certain security only if they are aware of this security. My
explanation relies on the fact that unit offerings are a com-
bination of common stock and warrants that are separable
and tradable after the offering. Under the assumption that
some investors will sell one security and keep the other
or sell both securities to different investors, this would
lead to a mechanical increase in the firm’s investor aware-
ness compared to similar offerings that sell only common
stock. This assumption of trading fragmentation of war-
rants and shares can be reasoned by findings in Ami-
hud et al. (2003).2Further, according to Merton (1987), an
increase in investor awareness should increase firm value.
Even though issuing units can increase firms’ investor
awareness and therefore firm value, it may not be the best
choice for all IPO firms. There are several possible reasons
for firms not to issue units. First of all, Merton’s model
implies that the marginal benefit of increasing investor
awareness is diminishing as the number of investors
increases3and Merton also assumes that the marginal
cost of increasing investor awareness increases with the
number of investors already informed. In other words,
as the investor awareness increases, bringing an extra
investor would benefit the firm less but cost the firm more.
Companies would try to raise their investor awareness
until they reach the equilibrium where the marginal
benefit equals the marginal cost. Large and matured IPO
firms (e.g., Twitter, Facebook) should have more publicity
already before their IPOs. For these firms, the marginal
cost of increasing investor recognition through issuing
warrants may outweigh the marginal benefit of doing
so. Therefore, a further increase in investor awareness
is not in the best interests of current shareholders for
these firms at the time of IPO. In addition, there are
costs associated with issuing units. When warrant holders
exercise their warrants, they purchase shares at a discount
price and become new shareholders, which could hurt
the interest of existing shareholders due to the dilution
effect.
While large and mature IPO firms may not find it opti-
mal to issue units, this might be the best choice for smaller,
younger and riskier firms, who are typically brought to
the market by low-prestige underwriters. These firms nor-
mally receive less publicity before going public. As a result,
it is worthwhile for them to try to increase their exposure
to the public as the marginal benefit of increasing investor
awareness is more than the marginal cost. As an alterna-
tive to conducting public relation events which could be
too expensive, issuing units would be the less costly/more
efficient way to increase investor awareness. In addition,
Demers and Lewellen (2003) claim that underpricing helps
IPO firms to attract market attention and create publicity.
Therefore, underpricing can be a complementary tool for
unit firms to increase investor recognition.
Correspondingly, I propose four hypotheses. First, unit
IPO issuers should have less pre-IPO publicity before the
offering. These firms may find it costly and/or inefficient
to conduct advertising and public relation events. As an
alternative, they can go public by issuing units. Second,
unit IPO firms should experience a greater increase in the
number of shareholders than comparable share-only firms
as their warrants are exercised. Third, firms issuing units
are underpriced to a greater extent as they employ under-
pricing as a complementary tool. Lastly, as investoraware-
ness increases after the offerings, unit firms have higher
firm value than comparable share-only IPO firms. Com-
pared with the sample of traditional share-only IPO firms,
unit IPO firms are on average younger and smaller. In
other words, on the firm size or age distribution of all
IPOs, unit IPOs concentrate on one tail of the distribu-
tion. Consequently, simply comparing the average num-
ber of shareholders and the average firm value of unit IPO
firms to those of share-only IPO firms can be misleading.
Therefore, I control other factors while comparing unit
firms with share-only firms, especially firm size and age.
This paper focuses on distinctions between unit firms and
“comparable” share-only firms.
The investor recognition explanation in this paper
is not mutually exclusive from the two existing theo-
ries by Schulz (1993) and Chemmanur and Fulghieri
(1997). Instead, given that some findings cannot be fully

Get this document and AI-powered insights with a free trial of vLex and Vincent AI

Get Started for Free

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT