The Time‐Consistent Public Goods Provision

AuthorSHIGEO MORITA
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12209
Published date01 December 2016
Date01 December 2016
THE TIME-CONSISTENT PUBLIC GOODS PROVISION
SHIGEO MORITA
Osaka University
Abstract
In this study, we reconsider the optimal nonlinear tax problem with
the public good from the perspective of the commitment issue and ex-
amine how it affects the condition of the public good provision. We
show that the Samuelson rule should be modified when the govern-
ment cannot commit and the skill types of taxpayers are revealed in
the first period. This is true even if the preference of the taxpayers is
separable and additive with respect to consumption and leisure. Our
analysis also shows how the lack of commitment affects the formula of
the marginal cost of public funds and the level of public good provi-
sion. Our findings imply that the level of the public good may be exces-
sive in comparison to the case where the government can commit to its
tax policy.
1. Introduction
It is known that the Samuelson rule for the optimal provision of the public good, which
equates the sum of marginal willingness to pay for the public good to the marginal
cost of providing the public good, breaks down in the presence of the distortionary
cost of taxation required to finance the public good. Pigou (1928) stated that when
the public good is financed by a distortionary tax, the dead weight loss raises the social
marginal cost of public goods above the case of a nondistortionary tax (referred to as the
Pigou effect). More recently, Boadway and Keen (1993) considered the case in which
the public good is financed using nonlinear income taxation ´
alaMirrlees (1971). They
showed that it is generally optimal to deviate from the Samuelson rule in providing the
public good, except when the utility function of taxpayers is separable in leisure. On
the other hand, since some public goods have the property of durable goods, a dynamic
setting is necessary in order to analyze the optimal condition of the public good. The
traditional dynamic Samuelson rule implies that the marginal social benefit of public
Shigeo Morita, Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University,1-7, Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka
560-0043, Japan (ngp024ms@student.econ.osaka-u.ac.jp).
I would like to express my sincere gratitude to the editors John P. Conley and Myrna Wooders, the
associate editor Helmuth Cremer, and anonymous referees for their helpful comments that greatly
improved the paper.I am especially grateful to Yukihiro Nishimura and participants at the Kansai Public
Economic Workshop.
Received May 29, 2016; Accepted June 9, 2016.
C2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 18 (6), 2016, pp. 923–941.
923
924 Journal of Public Economic Theory
goods should be equal to the marginal cost, the static Pigou effect, and the dynamic
efficiency effect.
This paper analyzes the issue of time consistency. Aronsson and Grandlund (2011)
focused on the situation where taxpayers have a time-inconsistent preference for the
public good. Assuming a paternalistic government, they showed that the social optimal
condition of the public good provision should deviate from the Samuelson rule. Gaube
(2007) pointed out two types of issues in the nonlinear income tax problem with two
periods. The first issue is the choice of the tax base. In other words, do the nonlinear
tax functions depend on a current income or incomes in both periods? In the model
of Gaube (2007), a nonlinear tax is a function of current income, and the government
can commit to its policy in the future. Under such formulation, he showed that the
nondistortion at the top result, namely that the high-skill consumer should face a zero
marginal tax rate and the low-skill consumer should face a positive marginal tax rate at
the optimum, should be violated. The second issue concerns the ratchet effect, which
is the focus of this paper. In using information revealed by taxpayers in the first period,
the government can re-optimize its tax schedule in the second period to allow the in-
crease of the social welfare. However, if the taxpayers are aware of this re-optimization,
then they may adjust their behavior in the first period to conceal their information.
The ratchet effect never appears if the government can commit its policy to all peri-
ods in the first period. However, this commitment is not credible and, therefore, not
time-consistent. Roberts (1984) analyzed this issue by studying the optimal income tax-
ation under noncommitment and an infinite time horizon. Proposition 8 in the paper
posited that the separation of types will not occur under an infinite horizon. More re-
cent studies on this topic include those of Apps and Rees (2006), Bisin and Rampini
(2006), Brett and Weymark (2008), Krause (2009), Guo and Krause (2011, 2013), and
Berliant and Ledyard (2014). However, no previous studies have examined how the
ratchet effect affects the public good provision. Therefore, we analyze how the public
good provision is impacted by the ratchet effect. To the best of our knowledge, this
paper is the first to examine the implications of the ratchet effect for the public good
provision.
To clarify the effect, we utilize two periods and the partial equilibrium version of the
model discussed in Pirttil¨
a and Tuomala (2001). The new dynamic public finance (here-
after NDPF) approach produces interesting lines of thought within macroeconomics
and pubic finance. It includes studies by Golosov, Tsyvinski, and Werning (2006) and
Acemoglu, Golosov, and Tsyvinski (2008). The model applied in such studies is a non-
linear tax problem with multiperiods, and stochastic-type changes are assumed to occur.
In this paper, for simplicity, there are no stochastic-type changes over time. We show
that, when the government cannot commit to its policy and the skill types of taxpayers
are revealed in the first period, the Samuelson rule no longer applies even if the utility
function is separable in labor. Moreover, this paper examines how the lack of commit-
ment by the government affects the formula of the marginal cost of public funds (here-
after MCPF), which plays an important role in assessing the optimality of government
spending.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the model
and considers the commitment case as the benchmark case. Section 3 analyzes the time-
consistent public goods provision. As an additional analysis, numerical examples in
Section 4 confirm that the ratchet effect also impacts the level of social welfare and
public goods. Section 5 concludes. The proofs of our main results are presented in the
Appendix.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT