The Social, Spatial, and Economic Roots of Urban Inequality in Africa: Contextualizing Jane Jacobs and Henry George

Date01 May 2015
Published date01 May 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12101
AuthorFranklin Obeng-Odoom
The Social, Spatial, and Economic Roots of
Urban Inequality in Africa: Contextualizing
Jane Jacobs and Henry George
By FRANKLIN OBENG-ODOOM*
ABSTRACT. Unravelling the social and economic roots of urban
inequality in Africa has remained a thorny issue in African political
economy. Stripped to its bare essentials, the critical questions are who
causes urban inequality, what causes it, and how it is caused? While all
different, the questions are interrelated. Answering the “who causes
inequality” question requires a related analysis of what and why, and
that is connected to the how question. Indeed, the how question has
two parts—how inequality is caused and how itcan be addressed. Both
are connected to the why question and to its resolution. Unfortunately,
while studies about urban inequality abound, they tend to hive off one
aspect or another of the tripartite questions on inequality and, even
worse, they study the three questions separately. This article tries to
overcome the existing atomistic and piecemeal approach to the study
of urban inequality in Africa by contextualizing the work of Jane Jacobs
and Henry George, who took a holistic view of urban inequality. It
argues that Jacobsianism and Georgism have much to offer in terms of
understanding urban inequality in Africa, but neither analysis goes far
enough to be able to serve as a solid foundation for policy. Ultimately,
it is in their approach to urban analysis—the emphasis on context, on
actual urban problems, inductivism, and some of their mechanisms for
change such as George’s land tax and cautious abstraction, in that
order, along with their combined vision—which I call “diversity in
equality”—that can add to the insights of postcolonialism in
understanding and transforming urban inequality in Africa.
*Senior Lecturer in Property Economics at the School of Built Environment, Univer-
sity of Technology Sydney in Australia; Visiting Research Fellow, United Nations
Research Institute for Social Development (UNRISD). E-mail: Franklin.Obeng-
Odoom@uts.edu.au. Thanks to Prof. Heather MacDonald for earlier discussion on the
work of Jane Jacobs.
American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 74, No. 3 (May, 2015).
DOI: 10.1111/ajes.12101
V
C2015 The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc.
Introduction
Inequality everywhere is on the rise, but in African cities, the rise is
meteoric. So, The State of African Cities 2010 was devoted to gover-
nance, inequality, and urban land markets (UN-HABITAT, 2010). This
inequality is spatial, social, and economic. It is within, between, and
across urban areas and cities. It also exists between city and country. In
spite of this growing inequality in cities in Africa, it is the growth record
of Africa and its potential for more consumption that receive the most
attention (Obeng-Odoom, 2014).
The Economist Intelligence Unit (2013) has praised “Africa”s growing
influence,” highlighting the centrality of cities to the story. According to
the Unit, recent research shows that residents in African cities spend
94.4 percent more per capitathan those in the countryside in 2013. This
is one indication that for the Unit and many other economists, the anal-
ysis of urban economic development can end at per capita considera-
tions that do not take into account distribution of income and other
resources within cities. Yet, the message from the recent immolation of
Mohamed Bouazizi on the streets of Tunisia, and the resulting
“revolution” in North Africa, the Arab World, and even the Western
world seen in the “Occupy Wall Street Movement,” is clear enough,
even among mainstream analysts such as Hernando de Soto, who inter-
viewed friends and family of Bouazizi (de Soto 2011): inequality in Afri-
ca’s urban centers can send the world system into a tailspin. It is not
enough, however, to recognize that inequality is a problem and com-
ment on its prognosis or ramifications:other aspects of urban inequality
must be addressed.
When the fanfare about inequality is removed, the critical questions
to answer are who cause inequality, why, and how they cause it. While
all different, the questions are interrelated. Answering the “who cause
inequality” question requires a related analysis of why they do so and
that is connected to the question of how they achieve that result.
Indeed, the how question has two parts—how it is caused and how it
can be addressed. All of these questions are interrelated. The flaw in
the current literature on inequality in Africa is to separate one aspect or
another and study each one separately. Even the mammoth State of
African Cities on inequality suffered this downside, as a review of the
Roots of Urban Inequality in Africa 551
report for the journal Cities pointed out (Obeng-Odoom 2013a). If we
are to make progress on understanding cities in order to transform
them, it is crucial to connect all the dots and answer the inequality
questions simultaneously and holistically.
Two thinkers who dealtwith and delved into these interrelated issues
and whose perspectives have remained enduring, perhaps endearing,
to social reformers, were Jane Jacobs and Henry George. Both sought
to deal with urban space and inequality and, in doing so, both were
against mainstreamideas of their time. While they were both Americans
and wrote about America, their ideas were intended to percolate urban
studies the world over, while maintaining a critical link to the context
that birthed the ideas. Jacobs’s (1962: 16) exhortation on the issue
requires full quotatio n:
I hope no reader will try to transfer my observations into guides as to
what goes on in towns, or little cities, or in suburbs which still are subur-
ban. Towns, suburb and even little cities are totally different organisms
from great cities ... To try to understand town in terms of big cities will
only compound confusion.
I hope readers will constantly and skeptically test what I say against their
own knowledge of cities and of urban behavior.
So, while she warned against uncritical application of her ideas,
Jacobs encouraged critical consideration. Henry George is more gener-
alist in Progress and Poverty but takes a similarly cautious stance in the
Science of Political Economy (1898). Yet, the application of Jacobsian
and Georgist ideas has been mainly limited to industrial societies. Jones
(1988: 488) observed that: “In the 1880s the American Henry George
made a revolutionary attack on the problem of poverty in industrial
society” (emphasisadded). Many other articles have been published on
Georgism, but mostly if not entirely, on industrial society. Georgist
ideas have been applied elsewhere (see Cui 2011 for an application to
the semi-industrialized societies of Asia, notably China), including Afri-
can societies, notably Northern Nigeria (Shenton 1986; Cowen and
Shenton 1991a, 1991b) and Ghana (Obeng-Odoom 2014a, 2014b), but
this work is embryonic and rarely urban-focused. Similar concerns
apply to Jane Jacobs, whose work has been celebrated globally but
The American Journal of Economics and Sociology552

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT